ITIF Logo
ITIF Search

The Process of Creative Destruction, Illustrated: The US Retail Industry

The Process of Creative Destruction, Illustrated: The US Retail Industry
October 3, 2022

The process of “creative destruction,” whereby new technologies and business models displace old ones, is key to growth and innovation. The evolution of the retail industry illustrates why it is beneficial and sheds light on the pitfalls of current legislative and regulatory efforts to limit it.

KEY TAKEAWAYS

The evolution of retail, including the rise of department stores, big box stores, and now online marketplaces, is a story of “creative destruction,” a term Joseph Schumpeter coined to describe the process of disruptive and beneficial innovation.
Online marketplaces, the newest retail business model, contribute to the rising labor productivity of electronic shopping and mail-order houses, which has surpassed the labor productivity of big box stores in recent years.
The history of creative destruction in retail follows a pattern: 1) Disruptive innovations attract consumers, reducing incumbents’ market share. 2) Disgruntled incumbents call for intervention. 3) Enforcers respond with regulations to thwart disruption.
Today’s resurgence of antitrust populism runs the risk of repeating historical antitrust errors that primarily focused on protecting inefficient incumbents at the expense of retail shoppers.

Key Takeaways


Contents

Key Takeaways 1

Introduction. 2

The Department Store: An Invention of the Industrial Revolution. 4

The Birth of Department Stores: Cathedrals of Novelties 4

The Success of Department Stores: Disruptive Competition Through Innovation. 7

An Improved Business Model: The Chain Stores 12

The Emergence of the Chain Store Business Models 13

Innovation and Efficiency of Chain Stores 14

Supersize Retail: Big Box Stores 20

The Rationale Behind Big Box Stores 20

The Disruption of Big Box Stores 22

Retail Reinvented: The Rise of Online Marketplaces 26

The Process of Creative Destruction and Online Retail 26

Competing Through Innovation: Consumer-Centric Business Models 28

Conclusion. 32

Endnotes 34

Introduction

Harry S. Truman once said, “Progress occurs when courageous, skillful leaders seize the opportunity to change things for the better.”[1] Yet, few important changes occur without opposition. In the latter half of the 19th century, the department store developed as a new retail form that inevitably reduced the market share of wholesalers and smaller specialty stores. As the department store expanded, it brought new economic efficiencies, including lower costs and prices. Chain stores simultaneously emerged during this period but did not see their peak until the early 20th century when their operations grew to encompass multiple states. The formulation of these novel business practices further stimulated economic efficiencies. Consequently, chain stores’ success in the economy inspired other retailers to adapt their model and practices, thus pioneering the big box store (e.g., Walmart, Target, and Home Depot). Similar to previous stages of the retailing evolution, the big box store also generated economic benefits. As technology evolves, the online marketplaces of today further enhance the economic benefits shoppers experience.

Yet, despite the economic benefits each stage of retailing brought, retail innovators nevertheless experienced strong opposition from small businesses, political leaders, and critics. Often, critics claimed that these retailers utilize anticompetitive measures to harm smaller retailers. However, in reality, opponents feared the power of the creative destruction process that disrupts less efficient forms of retailing. Unable to innovate and match evolving consumer preferences, small shopkeepers weaponized antitrust and other policy tools to thwart innovative retailing. As Atkinson and Lind noted, “The fact is that every retail innovation in American history—from the mail-order catalog to chain stores to Internet-based home delivery—has been denounced by incumbent businesses as a threat to the American way of life, when in fact it was only a threat to their outmoded corporate models.”[2]

As a result of their fear, critics used and continue to use a host of tactics to limit economically efficient practices new forms of retailers utilize. Antitrust represents a prime vehicle for advancing this small producer protectionism.[3] Herbert Hovenkamp warned, “There’s never been any viable theory that has articulated small-business protectionism at the expense of consumers as a viable antitrust goal.”[4] Such protectionism represents a critical obstacle to unleashing the beneficial power of what Joseph Schumpeter coined “the process of creative destruction.”[5] Today, online marketplaces face the brunt of the backlash from legislators, antitrust enforcers, and anti-big-business activists in the form of regulations, lawsuits, and legislation. The Institute for Local Self-Reliance has asserted, “To restore an open, competitive online market, policymakers must … break up Amazon along its major lines of business … by separating Amazon’s third-party marketplace from its retail division, and spinning off its cloud services and other major divisions into stand-alone companies.”[6]

The story of the retail industry informs antitrust populists that refraining from welfare-decreasing and innovation-deterring policies will prevent them from repeating the errors of the past—namely, thwarting the process of creative destruction in the name of protecting inefficient competitors.

Antitrust has represented the prime vehicle for advancing small producer protectionism. Such protectionism represents the main obstacle to unleashing the beneficial power of creative destruction.

Department stores, chain stores, big box stores, and now online marketplaces all represent different stages of what is, each time, another step in advancing innovative retailing. Nevertheless, populist views, which weaponize the notion of “fair competition” to impose less competition and innovation at the expense of consumers, continue to attack this relentless process of displacement.

The intellectual father of this backlash is former Supreme Court Justice Louis D. Brandeis. In his day, Brandeis advanced a vision of antitrust aimed at impeding innovative retailing against what he considered a “curse of bigness.” Today, Neo-Brandeisians have identified the disruptive power of online marketplaces as a justification for a modern view of the old small producer protectionism.[7] This “Brandeisian localism” opposing disruptive innovations constituted an influential force behind the regulatory and antitrust opposition to the process of creative destruction in the retail industry.[8] Both throughout history and in the present, populist opposition to disruptive innovations of large-scale retailers combined with consumers’ attraction to innovative retailing large, innovative retailers generate tear apart the retail industry.

The story of the evolution of the retail industry is the story of disruptive innovations—or how innovative retailers “competed against luck.”[9] Despite their diligence, small shopkeepers relied heavily on luck for their success: They had a relatively small customer catchment and their profitability relied only on the business of local customers. On the contrary, innovative retailers did not just stand idly by waiting for the business of local consumers. Rather, they anticipated and sought an understanding of what consumers wanted thereby enabling their innovative retailing model to succeed on effort rather than luck. These small retailers inevitably arranged their organizational structures much the same way large-scale enterprises did to maximize efficiency.[10]

Innovative retailing captures the consumer demand for minimal transaction costs (one-stop shopping with augmented product varieties), affordable items (price-cutting economies of scale and scope), and an enjoyable experience (from nice architecture and social interactions to remote consumption). Innovative retailers’ that fulfilled consumers’ desires were able to continuously compete against luck.

If policymakers want to see continued increases in Americans’ living standards, including working- and middle-class Americans, they should abandon efforts to rein in large, innovative retailers. These efforts only help a few small businesses at the expense of the majority of American consumers.

The Department Store: An Invention of the Industrial Revolution

In Emile Zola’s novel, Au Bonheur des Dames (“The Ladies’ Delight”), Zola described the emergence of department stores that wiped out small shopkeepers in mid-19th century Paris and how the disruptive nature of department stores sent small shops into bankruptcy and poverty:

[T]he middlemen—factory agents, representatives, commission-agents—were disappearing, this was an important factor in reducing prices; besides, the manufacturers could no longer exist without the big shops, for as soon as one of them lost their custom, bankruptcy became inevitable; in short, it was a natural development of business, it was impossible to stop things going the way they ought to when everyone was working for it, whether they liked it or not.[11]

Price-cutting department stores epitomized the process of creative destruction that Joseph Schumpeter would later conceptualize as the source of economic growth and the nature of the capitalist process. Department stores, then called “magasin des nouveautés” (“novelties stores”), were the main agent of this creative destruction in the novel by Emile Zola.[12] The process of creative destruction in retail has come to the fore with department stores. The birth of department stores reveals the nature of innovative retailing—and their success can be attributed to the consumer-centric efficiencies that underpinned their business models.

The Birth of Department Stores: Cathedrals of Novelties

Following in the footsteps of the Arcade Providence, one of the first enclosed shopping malls in the United States, Aristotle Boucicaut pioneered the first department stores—another form of an enclosed store—Le Bon Marché (“The Good Deal”) in Paris in 1852.[13]The department stores’ idea of a one-stop shop was revolutionary: “Finding everything from trousers to bedsheets and dishware to hairdryers and lipstick under one roof was an idea popularized in large part at Le Bon Marché under the Boucicauts’ leadership.”[14]

The creator of the first department store realized the importance of keeping consumers inside the store in a way that predated today’s attention economy. To keep consumers inside the stores, Le Bon Marché brought many innovations and became known as “a public palace”: Made of iron and glass, the department stores featured gigantic mirrors rarely seen until then. It was clear that “one of the best features of mirrors is the influence they exert on busy days. They put waiting customers in a more satisfied frame and induce them to wait without complaint longer than they would ordinarily.”[15]John Wanamaker, the founder of the Wanamaker store in the United States, recorded his 1896 excursion to Paris and replicated the use of mirrors “from floor to ceiling” in his stores.[16] The use of mirrors thus became critical in the development of department stores.[17]

Figure 1: The new staircase in Le Bon Marché, Paris. Lithography by Charles Fichot, 1872.[18]

image

Department stores soon mushroomed throughout Paris as “cathedrals of consumption.”[19] Consumers not only found novel products and enjoyed low prices but also freely accessed palaces designed to attract and retain consumers for social interactions.[20] In fact, not only the novelties of the architecture but also the items displayed turned department stores into cathedrals of novelties in which innovations from the building to the shelving drove the stores’ attraction. The innovations of the department stores disrupted local shops and secured their success.

Department stores emerged in the United States beginning in the mid-19th century. Mimicking the model of their European counterparts, American department store pioneers Aaron Arnold and Alexander Stewart acquired the “Marble House” and “Cast Iron Palace,” respectively, in the 1850s and 1860s.[21] Although Stewart pioneered department stores in America when he organized the Marble House into multiple departments, others ultimately carried the gales of innovations in retail. “Stewarts was by far the largest store in mid-century America, however, in many ways, it was simply the most prominent example of a trend toward innovative retailing throughout the country.”[22]

Indeed, at the close of the decade, the two pioneer department stores had set the precedent of what defined a department store: a large store that sold a wide range of products separated by departments. Copying this precedent, Lord & Taylor (1870s), B. Altman & Company (1876), Abraham & Strauss (1883), among others—including Stern Brothers, Ohrbach’s, Inc., Bergdorf Goodman, Bonwit Teller, Best & Company, Lane Bryant, Henri Bendel, Inc., Peck & Peck, Franklin Simon, James A. Hearn & Son, and R. H. Macy—saw their inception no later than the early 20th century in New York.[23] The draw of interested consumers and the profitability of the model encouraged the further expansion of department stores from Chicago to Los Angeles.[24]

Not only the novelties of the architecture but also the items displayed turned department stores into cathedrals of novelties in which innovations from the building to the shelving drove the stores’ attraction. The innovations of the department stores disrupted local shops and secured their success.

Department stores were ubiquitous in the development of America during the Industrial Revolution. Middle-class America and modern capitalism centered on consumer preferences originated from the rise of American department stores.[25] Indeed:

Department stores in the United States democratized luxury … the principal of first-come-first-served allowed a servant to be waited upon before an heiress … Obsequious acts, such as greeting shoppers, accepting returns, and treating all equally, regardless of positions in society, were elevated to the level of public service, something highly regarded in a democratic society.[26]

The great emergence and expansion of the department store across the United States brought many economic and retailing efficiencies not seen before. Due to their profitability and efficiency, some parts of the department store model are still in use today. Departments stores were “undoubtedly a phenomenon—perhaps the phenomenon of the nineteenth century and early twentieth-century retailing.”[27]  

The railroad boom of the 1840s and 1850s further funneled the development of the department store model as rail became a significantly more reliable, faster, and cheaper means of transporting products from the manufacturer to the retailers. Historian Alfred D. Chandler asserted:

The steam locomotive not only provided fast, regular, dependable, precisely scheduled, all-weather transportation but also lowered the unit cost of moving goods by permitting a more intensive use of available transportation facilities. A railroad car could make several trips over a route in the same period of time it took a canal boat to complete one.[28]

Every city in America quickly had its department stores, which themselves began pursuing their own price-cutting endeavors. For instance, Dayton’s department store in Minneapolis used its basement as a “quality discounter.”[29] Initially called the “Downstairs Store,” the discounter eventually became “Target.” [30] Discounters and membership stores such as Costco started to populate every city in America with one objective: lowering prices.[31]

Middle-class America and modern capitalism centered on consumer preferences originated from the rise of department stores.

But how can one explain the success and rapid expansion of department stores?

The Success of Department Stores: Disruptive Competition Through Innovation

The spectacular success of department stores brings “about ruin and destruction of small traditional commerce … for the ever-expanding grand magasin.”[32] This “triumphant march of modernity” leads department stores to expand rapidly.[33]

Department stores developed together with the rise of suburbs and malls, inevitably leading to a decline in disrupted small shops often located in downtowns.[34] Despite antitrust actions, the development of department stores was hardly stoppable, as figure 2 illustrates.[35]

Figure 2: Department store revenues indexed to average sales in the period from 1957 to 1959[36]

image

Department stores epitomize the process of creative destruction via innovative retailing. They offer new ways of selling items, thereby contributing to innovations that enable firms to outcompete competitors. As Joseph Schumpeter made clear, firm organization that maximizes consumer reach is also a form of innovation. As early as the beginning of the 20th century, the innovativeness of department stores was widely recognized: “The merchant may exercise invention in the devising of a new method of selling goods. The department store was an invention of this class.”[37]

So how did department stores emerge simultaneously in France, America, and to a lesser extent, England? One possible answer is mass production irremediably led to mass consumption: Efficient distributional facilities (e.g., railroads) enabled producers to sell an abundance of innovations of the Industrial Revolution created at a considerable scale. Michael Miller noted, for example, that France was the largest producer of cotton goods on the continent:

Mass production of [cotton goods] required a retail system far more efficient and far more expansive than anything small shopkeepers might be able to offer. Consequently, incentives on the part of producers or jobbers to stimulate buying in large lots, an initiative on the part of new merchants to purchase such batches at low prices, became a growing practice.[38]

In other words, the innovation of the Industrial Revolution (i.e., mechanization of industries) triggered a virtuous cycle whereby corporate scale led to mass production, itself requiring better and more efficient wholesalers that could offer items at a lower price and a greater scale than smaller businesses could. These innovations, which offered lower prices and managed to keep consumers’ attention through architectural prowess and social interactions, disrupted small shopkeepers. The revolution that department stores represented was as much on the shelves as outside: Low prices and an extensive range of products were offered in socially appealing and visually stimulating environments. With all their inconveniences (i.e., transportation and searching costs), small shopkeepers could not compete. Moreover, the Industrial Revolution meant that people had more money to spend while cities were growing and affordable manufactured consumer goods became more readily available.[39]

The revolution that department stores represented was as much on the shelves as outside: Low prices and an extensive range of products were offered in socially appealing and visually stimulating environments.

Department stores had many benefits, but none rivaled the primary benefit of offering consumers the lowest possible prices: The innovative retailing of department stores first and foremost, meant price-cutting for consumers.[40] As such, department stores implemented buying methods that would reduce the cost of products to as close to the cost of production as possible.[41] Since large stores required large quantities of purchases, they obtained “extremely favorable contracts” when purchasing products to fill their shelves.[42] Department stores incentivized manufacturers to reduce prices with their large-quantity purchases that enabled manufacturers to increase sales and reduce costs per unit of production.[43]Due to their purchasing power, department stores eliminated the middleman wholesaler while simultaneously lowering prices for consumers.[44]

One significant innovation of department stores was the introduction of fixed and ticketed prices. Consumers gained price transparency, and transaction costs dramatically lowered as the bargaining time virtually disappeared in an era of mass consumption and fixed prices.[45]For instance, department stores facilitated the expansion of ready-to-wear instead of tailor-made clothing.[46] As lower prices, quicker transactions, and mass production were quintessential to department stores, the rise of ready-to-wear clothing for the benefit of consumers is unsurprising.

In accomplishing their objective of lower prices, department stores increased retailing efficiency as the allocation of products to consumers increased instead of sitting idly in the supply chain. Although their purchasing power generated efficiencies, their high stock turn model, or “the number of times stock on hand was sold and replaced within a specified time period,” further incentivized low prices and greater economic efficiencies.[47]Department stores’ high stock turn model had one primary objective: to sell large quantities at low prices and margins in order to increase profits.[48]

Although it seems counterintuitive that lower prices increased profits, a 1925 survey of 650 department stores concluded that the high stock turn model reduced expenses for retailers that sold large volumes of goods.[49] For example, high-volume sales resulted in a 1.8 percent interest expense while low-volume sales resulted in 2.5 percent.[50] Thus, the high rate of stock turn reduced department stores’ total expenses. Moreover, high stock turn also increased profits. The same study of 650 department stores found that stores with annual sales of over $1 million received a net profit of 3.6 percent for every dollar, whereas those with sales of less than $1 million received only 1.9 percent per dollar.[51] The profitability reduced transaction costs as department stores sold more varieties of demanded products at lower prices.

Despite the business model’s superiority in the late 1800s and early 1900s, one of America’s largest department stores—Kohl’s—was recently in talks to be sold in an economically challenging environment.[52] Competition, mostly from online commerce, has exacerbated the financial difficulties of the department store business model, as figure 3 illustrates.

Figure 3: Monthly advance retail sales in U.S. department stores (billions)[53]

image

While previously department stores were the disruptor, even more innovative business models—mainly online marketplaces—are now the disruptors of department stores. Nevertheless, antitrust actions have historically challenged the innovative retailing department stores represented. Department stores may have been a success story for consumers; however, they were a failure for a sufficiently large number of small shopkeepers who fostered popular pressure to tame this innovative form of retailing for the exclusive benefit of themselves.

The Regulatory Opposition to the Innovation of the Department Stores

Department stores encountered heavy scrutiny from critics—most notably from the local shopkeepers efficient department stores directly disrupted. For instance, as soon as department stores emerged in the mid-19th century, Paris shopkeepers published a petition in the Journal des Économistes.[54]They considered it “horrible” that shoppers could buy stockings, handkerchiefs, shirts, and shawls in the same establishment.[55] In response, the government restricted the variety of lines of business within a singular department store, hence limiting the development of department stores.[56] In Germany, the opposition to department stores (Warenhaüser) often conflated with antisemitism on the assumptions that Jews owned these disruptive and efficient business structures. Tax and regulations applied to Warenhaüser.[57]

More specifically, the (mis)use of antitrust for blocking the creation and development of department stores was widespread in the United States. Supported by organizations and merchants who feared competition, the Illinois Senate passed one of the first anti-department store bills despite questions about its constitutionality in 1897.[58]Although it was likely that this bill would ultimately fail to become law, it did not deter critics of department stores (i.e., incumbent small shopkeepers) from continuing their attempts to obstruct the creative destruction of retail via the development of department stores.[59]

Signaling the immense support for inefficient retailers, New York Assemblyman Barry bluntly asserted in 1897 that department stores did not have a place in the economy, as they had destroyed “numerous previously prosperous tradesman.”[60] Thus, in the following year, the New York City Council introduced a resolution imposing a $500 annual license fee on each department store department.[61]In the city of Chicago, a local ordinance targeting department stores prohibited the “sale of any meats, fish or other provisions or any intoxicating liquors in any place of business where dry goods, cloth, and other specified goods are sold.”[62] Spreading quickly across the country, this negative sentiment appeared as far as Colorado, where various social organizations demanded that the Denver City Council pass an ordinance against department stores.[63]

As the opposition grew, backlash spread to the state level as legislation limiting the practices of department stores increased. Indiana, Wisconsin, and Missouri passed bills that primarily sanctioned department stores.[64] For example, the Missouri Anti-Department Store legislation required department stores to pay a $300 to $500 tax.[65] The intense opposition against department stores throughout the country to prevent the creative destruction of less-efficient retailers limited the department stores’ practices and thus the efficiencies they offered.

Fortunately, the backlash began to subside in 1899 when the Illinois Supreme Court ruled in City of Chicago v. Netcher that an ordinance targeting department stores violated the constitutional right to liberty and property protection.[66] Following suit, the Supreme Court of Missouri ruled that Missouri's Anti-Department Store legislation violated constitutional rights in Wyatt v. Ashbrooke et al.[67]These two court cases triggered the beginning to an end of the detrimental provisions against department stores critics supported.

In Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John Park & Sons Co., the Supreme Court made agreements between manufacturers and their distributors on the minimum resale price of the manufacturers’ products, “per se,” or automatically unlawful.[68] The Supreme Court considered those agreements “designed to maintain prices … and to prevent competition among those who trade in [competing goods].”[69]This prohibition enabled consumers to enjoy the low prices large department stores could offer often at the expense of disrupted local shopkeepers.

However, antitrust populism and the desire to protect small businesses following the Great Depression drove Congress to “punish” all large department stores due to the expansion of market power that disrupted local stores.[70] Congress passed the Miller-Tydings Act in 1937 that enabled states to enact “fair trade” laws. In other words, Congress allowed states to overrule Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John Park & Sons Co.[71]The act exempted certain kinds of vertical price fixing from antitrust laws. The objective of Miller-Tydings was to permit states to protect small retail establishments Congress thought department stores might otherwise drive from the marketplace.

The protection of small businesses against the price-cutting practices of department stores went as far as the passing of the McGuire Act, which made the Miller-Tydings Act even stricter. In Schwegmann Bros. v. Calvert Distillers Corp., the Supreme Court struck down in 1951 the “nonsigner” provisions of state fair trade laws.[72] These statutes provided that once a manufacturer signed a minimum price agreement with one dealer in the state, the agreement bounded all other dealers regardless of whether they signed it. To overcome the Supreme Court decision of Schwegmann Bros., Congress passed the McGuire Act of 1952, which amended the Miller-Tydings Act: The “nonsigner” provisions of state fair trade laws could therefore continue at the expense of price competition and innovations large department stores exerted in the retail industry. Only in 1975 did Congress pass the Consumer Goods Pricing Act, which effectively repealed Miller-Tydings, thereby restoring the precedent of Dr. Miles.

However, in 2007, the Supreme Court overruled Dr. Miles with the decision Leegin Creative Leather Prod., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc. that the appropriate standard for testing the lawfulness of minimum resale price agreements, also known as resale price maintenance or RPM, is the rule of reason, not the per se standard.[73] Under the rule of reason, the courts evaluate the effects of a trade restraint on competition in the relevant antitrust market. If a restraint’s effects benefit competition between rival firms more than they injure competition, the restraint will be upheld. Thus, the Leegin decision means that courts will now review RPM practices on a case-by-case basis.

Opposition to department stores also resorted to the populist “anti-bigness bloc” of the Warren Court to weaponize antitrust against the development of chain stores through mergers.[74]In Brown Shoe v. United States, the Court blocked a merger between Brown Shoe and G.R. Kinney because the merger could disrupt small retail competitors.[75] Brown was the 4th largest manufacturer of shoes, with 4 percent of the nation’s production, whle Kinney was the 12th largest, with 0.4 percent of the national production.[76] The merged firm would have merely owned about 2.3 percent of the 70,000 retail outlets in the country.[77] Rejecting Brown’s litigation-created argument that the merger would not result in efficiencies given the Warren Court’s opposition to efficiencies and low prices, the Court found that the merger would result in efficiencies, enabling the merged firm to charge lower prices thanks to vertical integration. The Court blocked the merger because of efficiencies, not due to their absence. The Court stood in the path of disruptive innovations: The artificial protection of locally inefficient retailers stopped creative destruction in the retail industry.

A few years later, the Warren Court repeated the economic pitfalls of antitrust populism with Von’s Grocery.[78]The case of United States v.Von’s Grocery “was a return to Brown Shoe with a vengeance.”[79] The Court crashed down a merger that would become a city’s second-largest grocery chain but control only 7.5 percent of the grocery business in that city.[80] Von’s Grocery involved the merger of Von’s, Los Angeles’s third-largest supermarket, with Shopping Bag, the city’s sixth-largest store.[81] The expansion of department stores and the trend leading to fewer independent grocery stores—from 5,365 in 1950 to 3,590 in 1963—were enough to justify blocking the merger (according to Justice Black, who delivered the opinion) regardless of the consumer benefits, contributions to innovations, and the necessary process of creative destruction in the retail industry.[82]

In conclusion, the regulatory restrictions and antitrust populism of department stores limited the full extent of the process of creative destruction. Courts and legislatures blocked their ability to buy at a lower price (i.e., monopsony power) and to sell a virtually unlimited range of items (i.e., vertical integration) at a lower price. The populism of the time attacked the very business model of department stores. Small shopkeepers represented political forces that successfully contained the disruptive innovations of department stores.

An Improved Business Model: The Chain Stores

The department stores undoubtedly brought a range of disruptive innovations to 19th-century Western economies. Multiple brands, low prices, a greater variety of products, and ancillary conveniences, such as unique architecture and restaurants, became readily available under one roof for consumers to enjoy. The size of department stores generated scope and scale economies, which incentivized purchase and resale in large quantities.

Another business model that contributed to innovative retailing emerged at the end of the 19th and early 20th century: chain stores. With the development of the railroad and the improvement of accounting systems, retail stores re-organized themselves to become national chains.[83] Mass production and mass distribution not only drastically lowered prices—thanks to the efficiencies of scope and scale economies—but they also offered consumers a greater choice of items. Atkinson and Lind noted that “the Amazon.com of its day, Sears, Roebuck was the most important. Farmers would wait with excitement for the latest edition of the Sears, Roebuck catalog because it gave them choice.”[84]

The disruptive nature of chain stores was even greater than that of department stores on the local shopkeepers. Department stores, prior to morphing into chains, enjoyed scope and scale economies when they brought together different brands under a single, unique roof; however, chain stores pushed the logic of scope and scale economies even further. The buildings themselves were uniformized to enable replication nationwide with the benefit of massive scope and scale economies.[85] In other words, the centralized brand management of chain stores generated standardized business models across the country. While department stores left each brand operating under its roof to purchase and sell independently, chain stores centralized functions, such as marketing and purchasing, generating lower costs and thereby lower prices for the final consumers.

The disruptive nature of chain stores was even greater than department stores on the local monopolies of shopkeepers. Department stores, prior to morphing into chains, enjoyed scope and scale economies when they brought together different brands under a single, unique roof; however, chain stores pushed the logic even further.[86]

The emergence and evolution of chain stores resulted in massive efficiencies for consumers and, correspondingly, an important antitrust backlash.

The Emergence of the Chain Store Business Models

The chain stores in the United States emerged around the latter half of the 19th century. The Atlantic and Pacific Tea Company (A&P), first established as a tea and grocery shop in the 1860s, was one of the first grocery chains in the United States.[87]Following its lead, the Jones Brothers Tea Co. (1872), the Kroger Company (1882), the five grocery chain stores that became the American Stores Company—Childs Grocery Co (1888), Acme Tea Co. (1887), Geo M Dunlap Co (1888), The Bell company (1890), and Robinson & Crawford (1891)—the H. C. Bohack Company (1887), and the Gristede Bros. (1891) saw their inception in the latter half of the 19th century.[88]

Imitating the chain grocery model, Woolworth, first opening in 1879, pioneered the five and dime chains that spread across the country.[89] Alternatively, drug chains further mimicked the chain model: Schlegel Drug Store (opened in 1850), Meyer Brothers Company (1852), T. P. Taylor & Co and Jacobs Pharmacy Co (1879), and Dow Drug Co (1882).[90]Other product lines and retailers—including department stores—would inevitably imitate the chain store model.

Figure 4: Kroger Grocery & Baking Co. stores (1882–1934) [91]

image

A period of immense growth and expansion in the 20th century followed chains’ emergence. For example, despite opening its 100th store 20 years after it started selling tea and groceries, A&P added a substantial 170 stores to its company in the two years from 1913 to 1915 and no fewer than an additional 1,600 stores from 1915 to 1917.[92] Similarly, the Kroger Grocery & Baking Company saw exponential growth in its number of stores in the 20th century. (See figure 4.)

As chain stores disrupted retailing through their innovative practices and model, many chain stores of the early 20th century would also inevitably become the target of disruption in the process of creative destruction as a new form of retailing emerged.

Innovation and Efficiency of Chain Stores

The emergence and rapid expansion of chain stores brought significant economic and retailing efficiencies throughout the 20th century. Like department stores, chain stores also aimed to offer their customers the best prices; hence, they adopted identical business models and offered the same economic efficiencies. Chain stores adopted the high stock turn model to offer low prices while maintaining high profits. As a result, they also streamlined the movement of goods in the supply chain and increased the efficiency of retailing. Moreover, they also offered a large product variety at a single location, thus reducing transaction costs for consumers. The only difference between department and chain stores was (and remains) the degree of efficiencies they offer. The economic efficiencies chains offer constantly expand as the number of stores within a chain increase.

Yet, chain stores did not rely solely on their sheer numbers to augment economic efficiencies. In their endeavor to provide lower prices, chain stores implemented a novel practice: integrating parts of the supply chain process in order to reduce costs. Integration permitted expense minimization and efficiency maximization for the benefit of consumers. For instance, instead of outsourcing warehousing functions, chains overtook the distribution process, including purchasing, storing, and delivering goods.[93]The purchase of inventory reduced the expenses incurred from products going unchecked or being damaged. The storage of inventory reduced the expenses incurred during periods of low stock resulting in the slowed distribution of products to stores and the illogical placement of stock in warehouses—both of which harmed efficient turnover rate.[94] Finally, the delivery of inventory reduced expenses incurred in unplanned and slow delivery routes.[95]Integrating these functions created an efficient system wherein chains could funnel inventory quickly from manufacturer to store to customer.

In their endeavor to offer lower prices, chain stores implemented a novel practice: integrating parts of the supply chain process. Integration permitted expense minimization and efficiency maximization for the benefit of consumers.

As a result, chain stores became a principal source of efficient retailing in the economy. Despite only accounting for 6 percent of all stores in 1948, chain stores accounted for approximately 23 percent of the total retail volume in the economy.[96] This is unsurprising considering some of the largest chains had increasing sales during periods of the 20th century. (See figure 5.) Consequently, chain stores further minimized prices while increasing supply chain efficiency and thus further increased the efficiency of retailing in another stage of innovative retailing in the industry’s evolution.

Figure 5: Sales of the 10 largest chains in the early 20th century ($millions)[97]

image

As Richard Schragger noted, the chain store revolution appeared quickly. And unsurprisingly, the disruptive power of the innovations the chain store model brought about generated a sudden anti-chain store movement: “Between 1920 and 1940, a loose confederation of independent merchant associations, local merchants, antimonopolists, agrarians, populists, and progressives sought to stem the chain expansion. By 1929, associations in over 400 cities and towns had formed to fight the chains.”[98]

The success of disruptive companies such as A&P, Kroger, American Stores, Safeway, and a national federation of independent stores (F. National) led these five companies to dominate the grocery market: The share of these top five companies in the United States increased from 4.2 percent to 28.8 percent, as table 1 illustrates.[99]

Table 1: Market share of the top five chain stores in the United States (C5 concentration ratio, 1919–1932)[100]

Year

A&P

Kroger

Am. Stores

Safeway

F. National

C5

1919

4,224

1,175

4.2%

1920

4,600

799

1,243

5.6%

1921

5,200

947

1,274

6.3%

1922

7,300

1,224

1,375

118

7.1%

1923

9,300

1,641

1,474

193

8.0%

1924

11,400

1,973

1,629

263

9.3%

1925

14,000

2,599

1,792

330

11.5%

1926

14,800

3,100

1,982

673

13.6%

1927

15,600

3,564

2,122

840

1,681

16.9%

1928

15,100

4,307

2,548

1,191

1,717

20.4%

1929

15,400

5,575

2,644

2,340

2,002

24.5%

1930

15,700

5,165

2,728

2,675

2,549

27.6%

1931

15,670

4,884

2,806

3,264

2,548

29.3%

1932

15,427

4,737

2,977

3,411

2,546

28.8%

More generally, taxation and antitrust populism epitomized the anti-chain store movement.

The Antitrust Opposition to the Innovations of the Chain Stores

Critics of chain stores did not learn from their predecessors that attempts to protect less-productive retailers were only hurting consumers and the economy.[101] “Between 1920 and 1940, a loose confederation of independent merchant associations, local merchants, antimonopolists, agrarians, populists, and progressives sought to stem the chain expansion.”[102] The opposition to chain stores garnered an extensive range of vested interests antimonopoly populists best represented, in a similar way, Neo-Brandeisians currently best personify this opposition:

In the 1920s and 1930s, a wide range of groups and individuals opposed the chains. Unions worried about wage pressures; farmers were concerned about chain monopolies for commodities; wholesalers felt threatened as retailers increasingly integrated vertically; African-Americans feared that chains would undercut black merchants and leave the black community at the mercy of white-owned chains; and the Ku Klux Klan criticized chains for taking over small-town markets and sending money out of the South. Antimonopoly Progressives, like LaFollette, and populists, like Huey Long, agreed in their objection to chains. Of course, so did the independent merchants, represented most prominently by the National Association of Retail Grocers and the National Association of Retail Druggists.[103]

First, anti-chain store taxes emerged in multiple states in the 1930s. From California to New York, including Illinois, Georgia, and dozens of other states, more than 20 states passed anti-chain store taxes due to increasing political pressure from a myriad of shopkeepers and their employees who opposed the disruptions of chain stores.[104]

At the local level, ordinances targeting chains passed in multiple cities. For example, the city of Danville, Kentucky, passed an ordinance requiring “cash and carry” grocery stores, which were essentially chain grocery stores, to pay a higher licensing tax.[105] At the state level, by 1927, critics proposed at least 20 bills, including a Maryland law imposing an annual $500 license tax on chains.[106] Two years later, a Texas legislator’s proposal of a bill requiring chains to “invest a certain percentage of their profits in Texas’ interest” furthered the anti-chain sentiment.[107] As the negative sentiment grew, nearly 400 cities developed novel approaches to suppress the expansion and operation of chains.[108]

Further emboldening taxes against chains, the Supreme court ruled in State Board of Tax Commissioners v. Jackson that the taxation of chains did not violate any constitutional rights and was thus legally permissible.[109] Hence, this precedent set off a streak of anti-chain store tax laws in 26 states over the course of the subsequent six-year period.[110] Louisiana passed one of the most punitive tax laws against chain stores in the nation: It taxed chains according to their total number of stores nationally, not simply the number of stores in the state. A&P challenged the tax.

In the case Great Atlantic & Pacific Tea Co. v. Grosjean, the Supreme Court rejected A&P’s claims. It upheld the tax precisely on the basis that there was ample “evidence bearing upon a variety of advantages enjoyed by large chains which are unavailable to smaller chains.”[111] After that tax law case, the disruptive competition of A&P became the target of a criminal antitrust case in 1946. Indeed, a federal district court and the court of appeals found A&P in violation of the Robinson-Patman Act in what was an attempt to enforce “perfect competition,” which always leads to poorer rather than a superior economic performance.[112] A&P was found guilty of using what scale offers: a monopsonistic power wherein the store can purchase large quantities at lower prices to outcompete competitors. Indeed, Judge Minton summed up the guilt of A&P:

The buying policy of A & P was to so use its power as to get a lower price on its merchandise than that obtained by its competitors.... It used its large buying power to coerce suppliers to sell to it at a lower price than to its competitors on the threat that it would place such suppliers on its private blacklist if they did not conform, or that A & P would go into the manufacturing business in competition with the recalcitrant suppliers.[113]

The same scale economies of A&P disrupted its competitors to the point they were unable to compete. The passing of the Robinson-Patman Act thwarted such disruption and slowed down the process of creative destruction for the benefit of inefficient competitors, not consumers.

As if taxes were not enough to limit chains, the same six-year period also saw the passing of fair-trade laws in nearly 42 states.[114] These fair-trade laws forced chains to maintain the retail prices manufacturers set despite the chain’s ability to reduce prices from efficiencies, as this would protect inefficient competitors from price competition.[115] Fortunately, as with all mistakes, rational actors retaliated against these anti-chain store provisions. In 1925, the Supreme Court of Kentucky ruled in Danville v. Quaker Maid that the city of Danville’s ordinance was unconstitutional on the grounds that it violated the Equal Protection Clause.[116] State supreme courts subsequently heard at least two other cases regarding anti-chain stores legislations.[117]

Furthermore, in opposition to the fair trade state laws, the New York Court of Appeals asserted in Double Day, Doran & Co. v. R. H. Macy & Co. that the “nonsigner provision of the statute [is] unconstitutional under both state and federal legislation” because it constituted unnecessary “legislative price fixing.”[118] Despite this early win, the repeal of state fair trade laws did not occur until the 1970s.[119] State fair trade laws only served to stifle the creative destruction of the retail and economic efficiencies chains brought.

Unfortunately, this period of legislative frenzy did not conclude at the state level and instead spread to the federal level.[120] Beyond the Miller Tydings Act of 1937, the main piece of legislation that upset antitrust principles to protect small retail businesses from the creative destruction of chain stores was the Robinson-Patman Act, which amended the Clayton Act of 1914 and entered into the few foundational acts—together with the 1890 Sherman Act and the 1914 Federal Trade Commission Act—that gave birth to American antitrust laws.

The Robinson Patman Act prevents a “seller charging competing buyers different prices for the same ‘commodity.’”[121]Written by staunch supporters of independent businesses, Senator Wright Patman and Joseph Robinson, the act’s main purpose to protect independent retailers was so blatantly obvious that it was known as the “Anti-A&P Act.”[122] Together with the Miller Tydings Act, which was essentially a fair trade act at the federal level, these two federal acts hampered the creative destruction in the retail sector as chain store practices became limited.[123]

Justice Brandeis proved to be the intellectual force behind the campaign to protect small businesses via the Robinson-Patman Act, irrespective of the efficiencies and innovations of large retailers. Indeed, in Louis K. Liggett Co. v. Lee, Justice Brandeis dissented from a Supreme Court decision overturning a Florida statute that taxed multi-store retailers in proportion to their number of stores.[124] Brandeis dissented from the decision, which overturned the Florida statute because the statute was designed to harm and discourage chain stores, irrespective of consumers’ interests:

The chief aim of the Florida statute is apparently to handicap corporate chain stores—that is, to place them at a disadvantage, to make their success less probable. No other justification of the discrimination in license fees need be shown; since the very purpose of the legislation is to create inequality and thereby to discourage the establishment, or the maintenance, of corporate chain stores…[125]

As a result of the Robinson-Patman Act’s design to prevent “hard competition” from disruptive chain stores in favor of a “soft competition” between inefficient incumbent retailers, a disagreement between the two federal antitrust agencies on how to enforce the Robinson-Patman Act quickly emerged.[126] While the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) aggressively enforced the Robinson-Patman Act to protect small retailers from competition, the Department of Justice’s (DOJ’s) Antitrust Division disagreed and instead encouraged competition over retail distribution—an aspect where chain stores had a considerable competitive advantage over locally inefficient retailers.[127]

The Robinson-Patman Act was the result of populist antitrust pressures aimed at lowering chain stores’ exertion of disruptive competition on local monopolies. Increasing competition was not its objective but rather protecting the existing local monopolies at the expense of consumers’ benefits and the numerous innovations chain stores brought into the retail industry.

Unlike the Miller-Tyding Act, Congress never repealed the Robinson-Patman Act.[128] Such inability to repeal a competition-decreasing and innovation-stifling act is notable because of the numerous calls of repeal from both sides of the aisle since its passing.[129] Robert Bork described it as “antitrust’s least glorious hour,” as “Congress made no factual investigation of its own, and ignored evidence that conflicted with accepted rhetoric” before passing the legislation.[130]

For instance, in SELAS CORPORATION OF AMERICA and Fram Corporation v. PUROLATOR PRODUCTS, Inc. case of 1958, the DOJ’s Antitrust Division filed an amicus brief in support of the petition for certiorari, contending that the FTC’s interpretation of the act to require a spilt-function distributor to pay the same price as an independent jobber that performed no warehouse function would impede competition in distribution and protect existing and possibly antiquated distribution systems from normal pressures of competition and innovation.[131] The DOJ’s Antitrust Division was not keen to let the FTC refrain chain stores from unleashing the power of creative destruction with aggressive enforcement of the Robinson-Patman Act, an action that would decrease, not increase, competition and innovation in retail, and more generally, in the way American consumers shop.[132]

Beyond its ability to limit competition and stifle innovation, the unfairness of the Robinson-Patman Act is patent when one scrutinizes which actor becomes liable under the act’s provisions. In that regard, the case of Kroger v. FTC is illustrative.[133]Accused of having induced a supplier of dairy products to sell at prices lower than those charged to other customers, the chain store Kroger was found by the Court of Appeals for the Sixth Circuit to have violated the anti-price discrimination provisions of Robinson-Patman.[134] But why was Kroger liable for merely purchasing items when it was the seller that price discriminated against the provision of the Robinson-Patman Act? In this case, the mere argument that the prices charged were offered in good faith to meet what is believed to be the competitor’s equally lower prices exempted the supplies managed from antitrust liability.[135] In contrast, the FTC and the Court of Appeals found Kroger liable for having simply been charged different prices. This case reveals the unfairness and arbitrariness of the Robinson-Patman Act. Sellers applied price discrimination and purchasers accepted it, but enforcement discretionarily exempted the contracting party (paradoxically the one charging differentiated prices) while finding the contracted party (the one subject to price discrimination) liable. The only justification for this economic unfairness and arbitrariness finds its roots in the enforcers’ distaste for intermediaries and platforms chain stores represented yesterday, and online marketplaces represent today.

Fortunately, given the ability of the Robinson-Patman Act to thwart the process of creative destruction in the retail industry, enforcers and courts have subsequently refrained from adopting an aggressive stance in enforcing the legislation.[136] Overall, “the anti-chain store movement was animated by nostalgia for an age of smaller-scale distribution, an age that by the late 1920s was rapidly falling away in the face of ‘bigness.’”[137]

Unsurprisingly, Neo-Brandeisian advocates willing to protect small retailers irrespective of efficiency considerations and innovation concerns attempt to revive the Robinson-Patman Act in order to drastically restrain the disruptive power of online marketplaces.[138] Anyone concerned with unleashing the process of creative destruction in retail should ignore these calls designed to bring the economy back to the “Stone Age.”[139]

A conjunction of mass driving, mass consumption, tax incentives, and city expansion with suburbs paved the way for the emergence of the next stage in the process of creative destruction in innovative retailing: the big box stores.[140]

Supersize Retail: Big Box Stores

Big box stores supersized American retail. The rise of these shopping “supercenters” brought mass consumption to another scale:

Supercenters are an important and rapidly growing big-box grocery retail format. Supercenters are typically larger than 180,000 square feet, combining both a large supermarket and a large mass-merchandiser within the same store. The most well-known supercenter retailer, Wal-Mart, opened its first supercenter in 1988 and is now the largest food retailer in the world.[141]

Many big box grocery retailers expand in size, thereby diversifying their already diversified lines of business to pharmacies, in-store bakers, full-service delis, bank branches, dry cleaners, and other lines of business.[142] Big box stores can either be big box grocery stores (e.g., Walmart), general big box stores (e.g., Target), big box club stores (e.g., Costco), or big box category stores (e.g., The Home Depot, Best Buy). Innovative retailing in suburban areas provide big box stores with the possibility of supersized retailing, enabling their massive scope and scale economies.

The Rationale Behind Big Box Stores

The efficiency of the chain stores led to mass consumption. This mass consumption itself called for the creation of shopping centers in the suburbs where families relocated en masse in the early 1950s.[143] The idea was to recreate the one-stop shop of the 19th-century department stores but with the convenience of accessible car parking as opposed to congested downtowns where department stores were usually located.

The 1954 tax reform that enabled retail entrepreneurs to take large deductions in the early years of shopping center construction triggered a huge interest from companies to build shopping centers in the suburbs where American families lived and looked to shop efficiently and locally. Thomas Hanchett noted that “suddenly, all over the United States, shopping plazas sprouted like well-fertilized weeds.”[144] Shopping center construction shot up drastically, from an average of 6 million square feet per year in the early 1950s to 30 million square feet from 1956.[145] In traditionally populated urban areas, supermarkets are small, with less than 20,000 square feet of grocery selling space. Shopping centers in developed suburban areas, on the other hand, have a grocery space and total selling space of 80,000 and 100,000 square feet, respectively.[146]

These shopping centers “functioned not as supplements but as competitors to downtown shopping.”[147]Soon, shopping centers would displace downtown retailers, out-competing them with low prices, more convenient shopping, and a greater variety of items.

The efficiency of the chain stores led to mass consumption. This mass consumption called for creating shopping centers in the suburbs, where families relocated en masse in the early 1950s.

Big box stores are defined as retailers that sell branded products in large, warehouse-like stores at low prices.[148] These stores emerged in the United States in the 1960s and expanded their extraordinary presence in the 1970s. In 1962, Kmart, occupying about 100,000 square feet of space, opened its first store in Michigan selling “nationally-advertised brand-name products”—including Polaroid, Kodak, General Electric, and Black & Decker products—at consistently low prices to consumers.[149] The Walmart stores similarly opened in 1962 and sold brand name products at a discount of up to 50 percent.[150] For example, it ran an advertisement that year that promoted Sunbeam coffeemakers for $13.47, 32 percent below the non-big box average of $19.95.[151]

In 1964, J. C. Penney spun off its own version of a big box store that “emphasized brand name products” at a discount in 180,000 square feet of space.[152] In the same period, specialty big box stores also began emerging in the economy. Toys  “R” Us pioneered the first big box toy store and offered approximately 18,000 different toys, including name-brand toys by Hasbro, Mattel, and Fischer-Price, in a single location.[153] Barnes & Noble became one of the first big box bookstores, selling best-seller books at discounts of up to 20 percent.[154] Staples, Office Depot, and Office Max expanded the big box model to office supplies in the mid-1980s.[155] In that same decade, Circuit City and Best Buy did the same for the name-brand electronics category.[156] The rapid emergence and expansion of big box discount chain stores in the latter half of the 20th century brought new efficiencies to both the retailing industry and the overall economy. Research concludes that big box stores provide a net good for communities since they are a “one‐stop shop” for the essential products and services customers need and can obtain at a reduced cost, thanks to scale economies.[157]

What is the effect of the entrance of a big box store such as Walmart to a local retail market? Does it disrupt local retailers, hence participating in the beneficial process of creative destruction? Or do local retailers manage to survive the disruptive nature of big box stores? The answer is both interesting and counterintuitive.

The Disruption of Big Box Stores

The entrance of big box stores negatively affected many mom-and-pop stores in certain towns, the disruptive innovation big box stores provide leading to small retailers being outcompeted. To paraphrase Joseph Schumpeter, the gales of creative destruction do not hit at the margin but at the very core of their business models.

But this destructive side of innovative retailing that big box stores represent (at least for locally inefficient retailers, not for the consumers) comes together with a creative side: New retailers emerge and provide complementary goods and services to the big box stores. The process of creative destruction works in full play with innovative retailing harming inefficient competitors; however, because consumer satisfaction appeals to big box stores, these retailers encourage new and more relevant local retailers to emerge.

Empirical research reveals that, counterintuitively, towns without big box stores experience a more significant number of losses of local retailers. Consumers vote with their feet and travel to neighboring towns with big box stores to enjoy highly efficient one-stop shops where new local retailers have recently emerged.[159] In other words, as competition expands geographically and innovation generalizes in the economy thanks to the creative destruction, big box stores appear as the dominant model of modern retailing.

Big box stores brought similar efficiencies as did their predecessors, adopting the high stock turn model to achieve a sizable profit despite low prices.[160] For example, Walmart adopted this model and sold, on average, 14 percent below its competitors while maintaining increasing sales.[161] Its low prices drew in rising U.S. net sales. (See figure 6.) Moreover, the retailer bought directly from manufacturers with massive quantity purchases, therefore benefitting from significant discounts despite the unreasonable prohibitions of the Robinson-Patman Act.[162] Thus, big box stores similarly streamlined the movement of goods and reduced the transaction costs for consumers. Big box store retailers offered price and convenience to time-constrained shoppers while simultaneously enhancing efficiencies.[163]

Figure 6: Walmart’s U.S. net sales, 1968–2022 (billions)[164]

image

Big box stores represent the third stage of the retailing revolution that generated additional efficiencies for the benefit of consumers and innovation.

In addition, big box stores also integrated the supply chain process to reduce costs while maintaining efficiency. For example, Walmart integrated “new service or product development, supplier relationship, order fulfillment, customer relationship processes, and its internal and external associations” to prevent any unexpected disruptions that would increase costs.[165] As such, big box stores also transferred goods efficiently through the supply chain, hence offering the same economic efficiency that chains offered.

Big box stores represent the third stage of the retailing revolution that generated additional efficiencies for the benefit of consumers and innovation. Reducing costs at the store level enabled big box stores to increase retail productivity. For instance, big box stores implemented self-service at the store level.[166] Self-service is described as consumers receiving fewer services. For example, once found in multiple locations within a store, cash registers were placed only at the front.[167] The justification for the implementation of self-service was that it not only lowered a store’s operational expenses but also led to a “net reduction in the combined total of other expenses, such as returned goods, pilferage, training, delivery, and credit.”[168]

Hence, big box’s self-service approach increased its operational productivity, as employees could fulfill other tasks. Alternatively, big box stores, particularly Walmart, also experimented with the use of a universal-price-code (UPC) scanner in the 1980s to further reduce labor inputs while also increasing the number of products it could handle.[169] The installation of these scanners in two stores resulted in cashier productivity rising by more than half.[170] In fact, labor productivity for general merchandise stores, including warehouse clubs and supercenters, experienced rising labor productivity from 1987 to 2007—seeing only a decline during the recession of 2008. (See figure 7.) Thus, the experimentation with new processes and technology that minimized costs while maximizing productivity at the store level generated new retailing efficiencies and contributed to productivity growth in the economy. A McKinsey report from 2001 highlights that retail contributes on average to nearly 25 percent of the productivity growth.[171] Of that 25 percent, Walmart contributed almost 6 percent.[172] As the disruptive innovations of big box stores disseminate in the economy, productivity growth further contributes to economic growth.

Figure 7: General merchandise store labor productivity 1987–2007 (2012 = 100)[173]

image

Retail contributed on average to nearly 25 percent of productivity growth in 2001. Of that 25 percent, Walmart contributed almost 6 percent. As the disruptive innovations of big box stores disseminate, productivity growth further contributes to economic growth.

Consequently, big box stores found a new way of contributing more efficiencies to retailing and the economy than their predecessors did. Big box stores expanded not only domestically but also globally, thereby contributing to uniformizing the retail shopping experience due to mass consumption while also enhancing global scope and scale economies. This undoubtedly led to some critics who favor both a romanticized approach to shopping and discarding low prices in the name of cultural preservation:

The Tesco hypermarket [in the Czech town of Hradec Kralove] sits on no man’s land where town meets country … an anonymous terrain of roads, warehouses, car showrooms, fast-food drive-throughs, and big-box retail developments. It could be France, it could be the United States, it might be Germany, Mexico, Belgium, Malaysia, the U.K., or Chile. Just another global retail zone, stripped of any geographical or national character.[174]

Nevertheless, big box stores represent another stage of innovative retailing that displaced some smaller chain stores and independent stores. Data suggests that while turnover (entry and exit) of retailers demonstrates the dynamism of the retail industry, big box stores proved more successful at expanding when compared with other smaller chain stores and independent retailers:

Turnover is substantial for all retailer types. Conventional supermarket retailers opened and closed between 2 percent and 3 percent of their stores each year, with store closings being more common than openings during the sample period. In contrast, supercenter and club store retailers frequently open new stores, supercenters increased their stock of stores by more than 10 percent in 2005 and 2006, but almost never close existing stores.[175]

Big box stores represent another stage of innovative retailing that displaced some smaller chain stores and independent stores.

The Antitrust Opposition to the Innovation of Big Box Stores

The repeal of anti-chain store legislation by the 1970s prevented similar roadblocks (e.g., unreasonable taxes and fair-trade laws) for big box stores. However, big box stores nonetheless faced backlash from critics who attempted to protect less-efficient mom-and-pop shops. Critics claimed that big box stores’ practices violated antitrust laws.

Radical opposition called for the breakup of big box stores. Unsurprisingly, Walmart became the prime target of the populists’ call for such structural remedies.[176] Barry Lynn, director of the Open Markets Institute and mentor of now chair of the FTC Lina Khan, has repeatedly called for breaking up Walmart (before making the same claim again with Amazon).[177] In “The Case for Breaking Up Walmart,” Lynn argued that we need to “protect all of our fellow citizens from Walmart and other such private autocracies.”[178]

Enforcers and competitors targeted Walmart with a host of complaints regarding predatory pricing. In Wisconsin, the Department of Agriculture, Trade, and Consumer Protection accused Walmart of selling certain grocery products below cost.[179] Crest Food in Oklahoma also made similar accusations when the company filed a lawsuit alleging that the big box store had violated the Oklahoma Unfair Sales Act.[180]In 1993, three drug stores in Arkansas made similar claims against Walmart, which ultimately ended up paying a fine of $300,000 when Judge David Reynolds ruled that Walmart had indeed engaged in predatory pricing.[181]

Often, these claims of predatory pricing against big box stores stemmed from less-efficient retailers and their supporters who view big box stores’ low prices as evidence of unfair pricing practices.[182] Yet, they seldom consider the role efficient business practices have in the reduction of prices. Consequently, it is unsurprising that the court overturned the 1993 Arkansas decision only two years later in Wal-Mart Stores, Inc. v. American Drugs, Inc., with the assertion that “legitimate competition in the marketplace can, and often does, result in economic injury to competitors.”[183]

Furthermore, regarding the Wisconsin complaint, the FTC highlighted in an amicus brief for Snider et al. v. Wal-Mart Stores, Inc. that it does not support the Oklahoma Unfair Sales Act, as it “limits the ability of retailers and wholesalers to engage in … competitive pricing.”[184] As an increasing number of enforcers have adopted economists’ perspective that predatory pricing is highly unlikely, critics’ predatory pricing claims have declined.

However, critics have found new ways to undermine the efficiencies of big box stores. In their attempt to protect inefficient retailers and prevent the creative destruction process in retail, critics and local governments have turned to zoning regulations to limit the expansion and entry of big box stores into their communities.[185] In particular, governments use store cap ordinances to limit the size of retailers, thereby preventing the construction of big box stores.[186] For example, Arroyo Grande in California limits retailers to 90,000 square feet and, in Rockville, Maryland, officials have suggested limiting retailers to 10,000 feet of space.[187] Zoning regulations such as these significantly limit big box store entry, thus hindering competition in the local economy and the creative destruction of inefficient retailers.

The opposition to big box stores, as previous opposition against disruptive stores, relied on dubious economic arguments and the weaponization of certain laws to protect small retailers from consumer preferences and the very process of creative destruction.

If big box stores were disruptive with massive scope and scale economies passed onto customers, the next stage of innovative retailing was even more disruptive, with online marketplaces combining the technological evolution with the convenience of remote shopping.

Retail Reinvented: The Rise of Online Marketplaces

With the emergence of online shopping, one would think that past antitrust errors and historical populist anger against innovative retail stores would not repeat themselves. Yet, online stores, particularly online marketplaces, have experienced a similar pattern of reactions: first, a phase of disruption wherein consumers favor innovation in retail, then a phase of vested interests that coalesce to ban or impede the disruptors, and finally antitrust momentum leading to a backlash of the innovative retailers in the name of protecting a softer, less-disruptive form of competition.

The pattern of disruptive innovations, populist reactions, and antitrust actions repeats itself with online marketplaces, similar to what happened to department stores, chain stores, and big box stores. Critics of disruptors use antitrust history to repeat and expand errors, not avoid them. Muris and Nuechterlein noted, when referring to the Neo-Brandeisians’ attack on any sizeable online retailer: “It took several decades of diligent analysis from academics, practitioners, antitrust authorities, and courts to draw the critical distinction between harm to competitors and harm to competition. It would be a doctrinal mistake of historic proportions to blur that line again. But that is precisely what the new antitrust critics propose.”[188]

Yet, the now well-known disruptive innovations to populist reactions to antitrust actions pattern is again repeating itself with online marketplaces.

The Process of Creative Destruction and Online Retail

The first online marketplace for retailing did not emerge until 1982, with the emergence of the Boston Computer Exchange, which consisted of an online bulletin board with listings of used computers consumers could purchase.[189] Despite its pioneering approach to retailing, the next online retailer did not emerge until 10 years later when, in 1992, the Book Stack Exchange, an online retailer that sold books, became one of the first to take advantage of National Science Foundation Network’s (NSFNET)’s acceptable use policies to sell online.[190]

Starting as “Cadabra” in 1995, Amazon launched an online bookstore with an improved customer experience and books that were, on average, 10 to 30 percent cheaper than those sold at other stores, atop a sales tax exemption when customers shopped online.[191] The advent of Amazon radically changed the consumer experience online.[192] For instance, when Amazon introduced “1-Click” shopping in 1997, the transaction costs decreased radically, and it “started a long history of innovation where Amazon systematically removed the pain points in the shopping process.”[193] Radical innovations such as free shipping, generous return policies, dynamic pricing, personalized recommendations, and reviews contributed to the disruptive nature of Amazon and the advent of mass online retailing.[194] In 2000, Amazon launched its marketplace, allowing third-party sellers (including its direct competitors) to operate on Amazon and reach an increasingly large customer base.

In 2006, Amazon Web Services (AWS) provided server capacity and an unprecedented exposure to a global consumer base that enabled small retailers to compete with big competitors. AWS removed the inefficiencies of having each third-party seller use a singular computing system, which prevents a nimble integration of services (e.g., database management, payment processing, storage components, etc.). The process of creative destruction finds a concrete illustration: Online marketplaces disrupted local stores with digital innovation but encouraged the emergence of third-party retailers that better matched consumer expectations. Amazon launched an online marketplace for books. Not long after, eBay, which originally started as an auction site before adding an online marketplace, began operating in 1995.[195] Overstock, another online marketplace, did not launch until 1999.[196]

The process of creative destruction finds a concrete illustration: Online marketplaces disrupted local stores with digital innovation but encouraged the emergence of third-party retailers that better matched consumer expectations.

In the first two decades of the 21st century, a host of online marketplaces—that allowed third-party sellers—emerged: Google Shopping (2002), Shopify (2004), Etsy (2005), Wish (2010), Facebook Marketplace (2016).[197] Walmart and Target, despite operating primarily big box stores, launched Walmart Marketplace and Target Plus, respectively, in order to keep up with the emerging digital platforms that disrupted traditional players.[198] According to Digital Commerce 360, 80 of the top 100 online marketplaces launched in the last decade.[199]

At the beginning of the effective emergence of online shopping, Clayton Christensen and Richard Tedlow wrote in 2000 that “it seems clear the electronic commerce will, on a broad level, change the basis of competitive advantage in retailing.” They referred to “disruptive technologies” as the way retailers fulfill the mission of “getting the right product in the right place at the right price at the right time.” They considered, “In retailing … Internet retailing marks [a new] disruption. A diverse group of Internet companies … are poised to change how things are bought and sold in their markets. These newcomers pose powerful threats to competitors with more conventional business models.”[200]

Experts and officials unsurprisingly underestimated the motivation of digital retail disruptors to bring their disruptive technologies into the mainstream markets, thereby radically outcompeting offline chain stores.[201] Digital retailing undoubtedly represents a radical form of disruptive innovation that shattered competitors unable and unwilling to adapt, adjust, and compete with low-cost, high-productivity online marketplaces. Now, the disruptive innovations of online marketplaces enable them to outcompete less-disruptive retailers forced to adjust or bow out of the market altogether:

Call it “apocalypse.” Call it “disruption.” Call it “revolution.” Whatever you call it, it is sweeping through retail, destroying old established brands, and changing the very experience of shopping. In 2016, Sports Authority shut down 460 stores, Walmart closed 269, Aeropostale closed 154, Kmart/Sears closed 78, Ralph Lauren closed at least 50, and Macy’s closed 100. The wave of destructive accelerated in 2017 with more than 8,000 store closings … Bankruptcy filings by US retailers nearly doubled in 2016 … It is clear that retail as we know it is changing, and with it, the very experience of shopping.[202]

Online marketplaces naturally have a global market to reach. Consumer demand drives the need for the increasingly productive efficiency of online stores. Consumers expected low prices, quicker shipping, a limitless variety of items, and more secure transactions that online marketplaces disruptively fulfill. The digital retail revolution epitomizes the process of creative destruction—displacing incumbents and creating more opportunities for third-party sellers in online marketplaces that offer competitive prices and broader choices.

Consumer demand drove the need for the increased productive efficiency of online stores. Low prices, quicker shipping, a limitless variety of items, and more secure transactions were consumers’ expectations that online marketplaces disruptively fulfilled.

Competing Through Innovation: Consumer-Centric Business Models

Amazon claims to “be the most customer-centric company on Earth.”[203] But what does it mean for an online department store to be “customer-centric”? It essentially means reducing defects in the distribution system to reduce the cost structure, which enables lower prices, better customer service, greater customer choice, and a dedication to offering customers innovative products and services.[204] This commitment helped online marketplaces develop a cost structure reduced to the extent that offline stores were unable to match, hence disrupting offline stores, leading most to bankruptcy and forcing many to adjust and compete through innovation.

Online marketplaces differ from their predecessor in that they do not operate in a physical location. As such, their business model and practices also vary quite a bit from previous forms of retail. Yet, online marketplaces nonetheless offer similar efficiencies. Despite not necessarily utilizing a purely high stock turn model, Amazon and other online marketplaces offer economic efficiencies in the form of reduced transaction costs. According to Mike Mandel, vice president and chief economist at the Progressive Policy institute:

The main point of ecommerce, when done right, is to reduce the time consumers spend shopping—the drive to the store, the search for parking, the endless trudging through the aisle … the shift to ecommerce over the past nine years [from 2009 to 2017] has saved American households roughly 64 million hours per week in reduced shopping time, or the equivalent of 1.6 million full-time jobs.[205]

Because online marketplaces exist in a virtual space, they can easily offer immense numbers of products to their customers. For example, Amazon offers close to 350 million products to consumers, a stark difference from the 120,000 Walmart’s big box stores offer.[206]In other words, simply existing in a virtual space reduces transaction costs to consumers, as online marketplaces are one-stop shops for consumers to find almost any product.

Moreover, online marketplaces augment this economic efficiency because consumers do not have to leave their house to find and purchase goods. They simply need to sit on their couch, connect their computer to the Internet, and scroll through web pages to find and order their desired products. The emergence of this new method of retailing eliminates the opportunity cost of travel time and the physical cost of picking up and putting items into the shopping cart and carrying the products home.[207]Hence, online marketplaces significantly reduced the transaction costs imposed on consumers, thus increasing retailing and economic efficiency. Moreover, due to their virtual nature, online marketplaces also eliminated the store costs big box stores faced, resulting in the stimulation of further economic productivity.

Being consumer-centric essentially means reducing defects in distribution to reduce the cost structure, which enables lower prices, better customer service, greater customer choice, and a dedication to offering customers innovative products and services.

Despite not having a physical store, online marketplaces continue to operate an efficient supply chain. For example, Amazon streamlines products through the supply chain when it acquires products from manufacturers, or vendors, in large quantities at discounted wholesale prices.[208] After receiving the products, it oversees the selling, pricing, and shipping of those products to consumers.[209] In 2017, its first-party sales accounted for nearly 22 percent of all Amazon sales.[210] Alternatively, third-party sellers also streamline the movement of products throughout the supply chain, since they acquire products from manufacturers before pricing, selling, and, for the most part, shipping their products to consumers. The online marketplaces can simply act as a place to connect these sellers to consumers and hence do not hinder the movement of goods in the supply chain for third-party products. Despite the differences, these processes generate the same retailing and economic efficiency that their predecessors offered.

Similar to chain stores, online marketplaces also integrate parts of the supply chain process to minimize expenses and maximize efficiency. For example, Amazon located its distribution centers closer to customers in order to integrate the storage and delivery of products, thereby reducing costs and increasing the efficient movement of goods to consumers.[211] Third-party sellers can also have Amazon ship their products and thereby take advantage of Amazon’s integrated supply chain process. As a National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) study highlights, Amazon’s integrated distribution network “realizes significant cost savings and economies of scale from network expansion.”[212]In fact, from 2006 to 2016, Amazon reduced its shipping costs by approximately 50 percent and prices for consumers by almost 40 percent.[213]In fulfilling their core leadership principles to “accomplish more with less,” Amazon successfully increased the efficiency of retailing through integration.[214] Unsurprisingly, its efficient processes have led to net sales of $470 billion, approximately $366 billion more than the big box retailer Target.[215] Moreover, online marketplaces contribute to the rising labor productivity of electronic shopping and mail-order houses (North American Industry Classification System (NAICS): 45411), which has surpassed the labor productivity of general merchandise stores, including warehouse clubs and supercenters (NAICS: 45231) in recent years. (See figure 8.)

Figure 8: Labor productivity of non-store retailers and general merchandise stores, 1987–2021 (2012 = 100)[216]

image

Online marketplaces further augment economic efficiency with their business model setup, enabling the entry of small businesses and thereby increasing product variety and reducing transaction costs for consumers. Online marketplaces enable small and medium-sized sellers to market and sell their products to a global consumer base despite the sellers’ limited budget. Research shows that online marketplaces contribute more than $145 billion annually to such businesses.[217] Nearly $30 billion of that contribution stems from cost savings in the form of “reduced cost of starting a business, operating and transacting sales, and lower costs of expansion” for small businesses.[218] As a result of these cost savings, online marketplaces reduce entry barriers for small businesses, hence increasing the product variety consumers face, as budget-limited entrepreneurs have a platform that enables and incentivizes their product development. Moreover, the enhanced product variety also enables consumer time saving, as more products are available to match the preferences of consumers.

The Antitrust Opposition to the Innovations of Online Marketplaces

Online marketplaces have experienced not only similar antitrust opposition to their predecessors (i.e., department stores, chain stores, big box stores) but also more concrete antitrust actions. Digital competition disrupts established players for the benefit of consumers, and unsurprisingly, Neo-Brandeisians battle in favor of established competitors irrespective of consumer welfare.[219]

First, the disruptive retailing online marketplaces represented was one of the main topics of congressional investigations, hearings, and, subsequently, antitrust bills.[220] In 2021, bipartisan legislators introduced at least three bills in Congress that targeted the practices and efficiencies of online marketplaces: the American Innovation and Choice Online Act (AICOA), the Platform Competition and Opportunity Act, and the Ending Platform Monopolies Act.[221] Among its many provisions, the AICOA prohibits the self-preferencing of private label products—a common business practice—despite consumer preference for cheaper products, hence limiting the efficient conduct of online marketplaces.[222] This prohibition will undoubtedly put online marketplaces at a disadvantage against competitors, hindering competition and innovation and making it blatantly clear that protecting less-efficient retailers is the supporters’ most important objective.

The bipartisan Ending Platform Monopolies Act Representative Jayapal (D-WA) introduced suggests that online marketplaces be broken up such that it “eliminates the ability of dominant platforms to leverage their control over across [sic] multiple business lines.”[223] Similar to the AICOA, this bill could potentially force Amazon to discontinue its Amazon Basics brand while unfairly allowing its offline competitors to continue to sell their private labels.[224] Moreover, it could also force the elimination of free shipping, a service that many consumers rely on, thus hindering retail efficiency.[225] The discontinuation of these two practices, among others, could inhibit competition while simultaneously harming efficient business models. Yet, critics of online marketplaces nonetheless advocate for this anti-competitive bill in order to protect smaller retailers from these legitimate and pro-competitive business practices.

Finally, the Platform Competition and Opportunity Act of 2021 also targets the expansion of online marketplaces to protect inefficient retailers. The bill asserts that platforms with “a net annual sales, or market capitalization greater than $600 billion”—essentially, large online marketplaces—cannot acquire “direct, nascent or potential competitors” in its attempt to prevent the acquisitions of start-ups.[226] However, in its attempt to protect less-productive businesses, and start-ups, the bill blinds itself to the fact that mergers and acquisitions “offer a means of acquiring knowledge, technology … reaching economies of scale and scope, and increasing innovative capacity” thus enhancing efficiencies.[227] Moreover, contrary to critics’ beliefs, acquisition is not necessarily harmful to start-ups and small businesses, as acquisition is an “important exit strategy for start-ups.”[228]

In light of the detrimental impacts unreasonable bills can have on the disruptive competition online marketplaces bring about, as seen with the European Digital Markets Act, critics should reconsider their support for the aforementioned bills.[229]

Second, the questioning of online marketplaces’ business models’ core from a range of lawsuits and administrative decisions has lowered the pace of the progress of creative destruction in retail.[230]

Third, an Executive Order identified “online marketplaces” as needing further regulations beyond what already exists. These regulations find their justifications on the rejection of the consumer welfare standard—namely, that companies engaging in pro-consumer activities may harm competitors.[231] The Executive Order states, “Too many small businesses across the economy depend on those platforms and a few online marketplaces for their survival.”[232]The Executive Order precisely considers that “to address persistent and recurrent practices that inhibit competition, the Chair of the FTC, in the Chair’s discretion, is also encouraged to [use] rulemaking authority … [regarding the] unfair competition in major Internet marketplaces.”[233] Accordingly, the FTC has considered that “the Commission will explore the benefits and costs of these and other competition rulemaking ideas.”[234]

Tackling “unfair competition” in online retail through rulemaking will likely be similar to previous attempts to slow down the disruptive nature of innovative retail—namely, regulation to protect small and traditional retailers regardless of the consumer benefits disruptors provide. In other words, Neo-Brandeisians will revive regulation through rulemaking in the spirit of the Robinson-Patman Act, hence hindering innovation. Consumer welfare, innovation in retail, and the very process of creative destruction that generates economic growth are likely to be the collateral damage of such regulatory interventions.

Conclusion

The story of the retail industry is one of creative destruction: disruptors relentlessly displacing small, less-efficient retailers before facing the same disruption that forces them to compete, often unsuccessfully, with new entrants. Innovation in retail is an endless race to greater efficiency and a better consumer experience. This process generates a cycle—a pattern of disruptive innovations, a reaction from displaced competitors, and a range of antitrust actions aimed at slowing down the process of creative destruction large retailers initiated, and the ultimate success of the new model, until the emergence of the next retail business model.

After more than a century, novel forms of large-scale stores maintain competitiveness and innovation with low prices. When incumbent retailers are faced with new, innovative competitors, the power of creative destruction will unfold and drive the incumbent retailers to bankruptcy, thereby opening the doors for the more-efficient and innovative retailer to become an incumbent firm in the market; inevitably, the cycle of creative destruction will repeat itself with a new incumbent. Consequently, from the Robinson-Patman Act to today’s antitrust techlash against online retailers, the backlash toward novel retailing business models rests upon misguided and unsubstantiated claims—the use of predatory pricing—that retailers are harming consumers, distorting competition, and stifling innovation. However, the reality is diametrically the opposite: The disruptive nature of large retailers generates vast consumer benefits, representing the ideal process of dynamic competition.

At each stage of the retailing evolution—from department stores to online marketplaces—critics are quick to implement legislation, regulations, and lawsuits that curb the efficient practices of new retailing business models. Through these methods, they seek to impose limits on the new generation of retailing in order to protect less-productive competitors.

The reality is diametrically the opposite: The disruption of large retailers generates consumer benefits, represents the ideal process of dynamic competition, and encourages innovation.

Yet, attempts to stifle the creative destruction of retailing hinders the economic efficiencies each new generation brings. Those who criticize online marketplaces today are no different from the critics of previous generations of retail. Today, proposed legislation and forthcoming rulemaking aimed at regulating online marketplaces represent the latest instance of a populist view of antitrust aimed at taming the process of creative destruction at the expense of innovation and consumers. Enforcers, judges, and elected officials should not repeat the antitrust errors of the past and instead allow innovative retail that benefits consumers.

About the Authors

Dr. Aurelien Portuese (@aurelienportues) is the director of The Schumpeter Project on Competition Policy at ITIF. He focuses on the interactions of competition and innovation. Portuese holds a Ph.D. in law and economics from the University of Paris II (Sorbonne), an M.Sc. in Political Economy from the London School of Economics, and an LL.M. from the University of Hamburg. Portuese’s latest book, Algorithmic Antitrust, was published in 2022 by Springer.

Trelysa Long is a research assistant for antitrust policy with ITIF’s Schumpeter Project on Competition Policy. She was previously an economic policy intern with the U.S. Chamber of Commerce. She earned her bachelor’s degree in economics and political science from the University of California, Irvine.

About ITIF

The Information Technology and Innovation Foundation (ITIF) is an independent, nonprofit, nonpartisan research and educational institute focusing on the intersection of technological innovation and public policy. Recognized by its peers in the think tank community as the global center of excellence for science and technology policy, ITIF’s mission is to formulate and promote policy solutions that accelerate innovation and boost productivity to spur growth, opportunity, and progress. For more information, visit us at www.itif.org.


Endnotes

[1].     “Truman Quotes,” Truman Library Institute, accessed July 10, 2022, https://www.trumanlibraryinstitute.org/truman/truman-quotes/.

[2].     Robert D. Atkinson and Michael Lind, “The War on Big Retail Is Nothing New,” The National Review, April 20, 2018, https://www.nationalreview.com/2018/04/amazon-critics-same-arguments-against-retail-innovation/; See more generally, Robert D. Atkinson and Michael Lind, Big Is Beautiful: Debunking the Myth of Small Business (Massachusetts: MIT Press, 2019).

[3].     Robert D. Atkinson and Michael Lind, Big Is Beautiful: Debunking the Myth of Small Business98; Daniel A. Crane, “Substance, Procedure, and Institutions in the International Harmonization of Competition Policy,” Chicago Journal of International Law 10, no. 1 (2009): 143 (“We are almost certainly better off with a system of antitrust heterogeneity with ‘better’ and ‘worse’ systems than we would be with a uniformly ‘bad’ antitrust system say, a worldwide regime of small business protectionism.”).

[4].     Herbert Hovenkamp, “Why Antitrust Law Should Protect Consumers First,” Wharton Magazine, Spring/Summer 2018, https://magazine.wharton.upenn.edu/issues/spring-summer-2018/why-antitrust-law-should-protect-consumers-first/.

[5].     See Herbert Hovenkamp, “Antitrust Policy and Inequality of Wealth,” Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law (2017): 5–6 (noting that “there are a couple of things worth noting about this approach [of condemning lower prices which threatens smaller competitors]. First, it clearly injures rather than benefits consumers. They are being robbed of the larger firms’ lower prices … Second, there is no obvious way of limiting its application … [I]t is hardly clear that this antitrust policy … would yield more attractive distribution of wealth.”).

[6].     Stacy Mitchell and Ron Knox, “Fact Sheet: How Amazon Exploits and Undermines Small Businesses, and Why Breaking It Up Would Revive American Entrepreneurship” (Institute for Local Self-Reliance, June 2021), https://ilsr.org/fact-sheet-how-breaking-up-amazon-can-empower-small-business/.

[7].     Lina M. Khan, “Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox,” Yale Law Journal 126, no. 3 (2016): 710–805 (Depicts Neo-Brandeisians battling against online marketplaces); Stacy Mitchell and Olivia Lavecchia, “Amazon’s Stranglehold: How the Company’s Tightening Grip on the Economy is Stifling Competition, Eroding Jobs, and Threatening Communities” (Institute for Local Self-Reliance Report, November 2016); David Streitfeld, “As Amazon Rises, So Does the Opposition,” The New York Times, April 18, 2020, https://www.nytimes.com/2020/04/18/technology/athena-mitchell-amazon.html.

[8].     Richard Schragger, “The Anti-Chain Store Movement, Localist Ideology, and the Remnants of the Progressive Constitution, 1920-1940,” Iowa Law Review 90 (2005): 1011.

[9].     Clayton Christensen et al., Competing Against Luck: The Story of Innovation and Customer Choice (New York: HarperCollins, 2016).

[10].   Ibid., 21–46.

[11].   Emile Zola, The Ladies’ Paradise (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1883), preface.

[12].   Emile Zola, The Ladies’ Paradise (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1883).

[13].   Michael B. Miller, The Bon Marche: Bourgeois Culture and the Department Store, 1869-1920 (New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1981); Vivian Song, “World’s oldest department store feels like the streets of Paris,” CNN, March 10, 2020, https://www.cnn.com/travel/article/le-bon-marche-paris-department-store/index.html; Natalie Clunan, “The Oldest Shopping Mall in America in Right Here in Rhode Island and It’s Incredible,” Only In Your State, May 10, 2018, https://www.onlyinyourstate.com/rhode-island/oldest-shopping-mall-ri/.

[14].   Vivian Song, “World’s oldest department store feels like the streets of Paris,” CNN, March 10, 2020, https://www.cnn.com/travel/article/le-bon-marche-paris-department-store/index.html.

[15].   Ruth Iskin, Modern Women and Parisian Consumer Culture in Impressionist Painting (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2007), 52.

[16].   Elizabeth Carlson, “Dazzling and Deceiving: Reflections in the Nineteenth-Century Department Store,” Visual Resources 28, no. 2 (2012): 122.

[17].   Ibid., 123; On the development of triplicate mirrors as device for consumption, see Kevin Hetherington, Capitalism’s Eye: Cultural Spaces and the Commodity (New York: Routledge, 2007).

[18].   L'illustration: journal universel, 23. März 1872, Seite 205, via Wikipedia, https://en.m.wikipedia.org/wiki/File:Le_Bon_March%C3%A9,_001.jpg.

[19].   Geoffrey Crossick and Serge Jaumain (eds.), Cathedrals of Consumption, European Department Stores, 1850-1890, (London: Ashgate, 1999); Jon Stobart, “Cathedrals of Consumption? Provincial Department Stores in England, c.1880-1930,” Enterprise & Society 18, no. 4 (2017): 822.

[20].   Paul Jarry, Les magasins de nouveautes: Histoire retrospective et anecdotique (Paris: Andre´ Barry et Fils, 1948), 139 (department stores were indeed “a play of a thousand diverse acts—each department a scene unto itself, where set design is all important, where metterurs en scene rival one another in ingenuity, an immense theater where the shoppers themselves take part in the show and become the stars of some gigantic music hall fantasy.”); See also Erika Rappaport, Shopping for Pleasure: Women in the Making of London’s West End (New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 2001).

[21].   John William Ferry, A History of the Department Store (New York: Macmillan, 1960), 42, 46.

[22].   Michael B. Miller, The Bon Marche: Bourgeois Culture and the Department Store, 30.

[23].   John William Ferry, A History of the Department Store (New York: Macmillan, 1960), 49–100.

[24].   Ibid, 124–132, 168–181.

[25].   Jan Whitaker, Service and Style: How the American Department Store Fashioned The Middle Class (New York: St Martin’s Press, 2006), 43; Robert Hendrickson, The Grand Emporiums: The Illustrated History of America’s Great Department Stores (New York: Stein and Day, 1979), 25.

[26].   Mark D. Bauer, “Department Stores on Sale: An Antitrust Quandary,” Georgia State University Law Review 26, no. 2 (2010): 261.

[27].   Jon Stobart, “Cathedrals of Consumption? Provincial Department Stores in England, c.1880-1930,” Enterprise & Society 18, no. 4 (2017): 811.

[28].   Alfred D. Chandler, The Visible hand: The managerial Revolution in American Business (Massachusetts: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, 1977), 86.

[29].   Mark D. Bauer, “Department Stores on Sale: An Antitrust Quandary,” Georgia State University Law Review 26, no. 2, 255-319 (2010): 268.

[30].   Ibid., 269.

[31].   Ibid., 268.

[32].   Masha Belenky, “From Transit to Transitoire: The Omnibus and Modernity,” Nineteenth-Century French Studies 35, no. 2 (2007): 412.

[33].   Ibid., 413.

[34].   Mark D. Bauer, “Department Stores on Sale: An Antitrust Quandary,” 272.

[35].   Ibid., 272.

[36].   Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED) of St. Louis, Index of Department Store Sales for United States (department store sales; accessed July 5, 2022), https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/M06F2BUSM350NNBR.

[37].   Edwin J. Prindle, “The Art of Inventing” (paper presented at the 2nd Annual Convention of the American Institute of Electrical Engineers, Milwaukee, Wis., May 28–31, 1906).

[38].   Michael B. Miller, The Bon Marche: Bourgeois Culture and the Department Store, 33.

[39].   Katherine Woodfine, “Behind the Scenes: The Edwardian Department Store,” Follow The Yellow, November 28, 2015, http://followtheyellow.co.uk/2015/11/the-mystery-of-the-clockwork-sparrow-behind-the-scenes-the-edwardian-department-store/.

[40].   Wesley Briggs Phillips, How Department Stores Are Carried On (New York: Dodd, 1901), 7.

[41].   Ibid., 25.

[42].   C. E. Fraser, “Can the small merchant compete with the large store?” Harvard Business Review 3, no. 4 (1925): 461.

[43].   Ibid.

[44].   Alfred D. Chandler Jr., The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business (Massachusetts and London: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, 1977), 224.

[45].   Jon Stobart, “Cathedrals of Consumption? Provincial Department Stores in England, c.1880–1930,” Enterprise & Society 18, no. 4 (2017): 822.

[46].   Michael B. Miller, The Bon Marche: Bourgeois Culture and the Department Store, 34.

[47].   Alfred D. Chandler Jr., The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business, 223.

[48].   Ibid., 227.

[49].   C. E. Fraser, “Can the small merchant compete with the large store?” 456.

[50].   Ibid.

[51].   Ibid.

[52].   Christopher Burch, “Kohl’s end talks of selling its company,” nj.com True Jersey, July 6, 2022, https://www.nj.com/business/2022/07/kohls-ends-talks-of-selling-its-company.html.

[53].   U.S. Census Bureau, Advance Retail Sales: Department Stores [RSDSELD], retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, September 17, 2022, https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/RSDSELD.  

[54].   Simon Ladwig-Winters, “The Attack on Berlin Department Stores” (paper, Shoah Resource Center, The International School of Holocaust Studies, 2000), 14.

[55].   Ibid.

[56].   David Walker, “This threat to France’s shopkeepers is just the latest in a 200-year war,” The Guardian, March 31, 2011, https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2011/mar/31/france-shopkeepers-business.

[57].   Simon Ladwig-Winters, “The Attack on Berlin Department Stores,” 14.

[58].   “The Anti-Department Store Bill,” The New York Times, March 25, 1897; “Object to Department Stores.: A Mass Meeting to be Held Against Them in Electric Park, Chicago,” The New York Times, April 21, 1897; “Largest Lobby on Record: Six Hundred Merchants of Chicago Start for Springfield, Ill.,” The New York Times, March 23, 1897.

[59].   “Anti-Department Store Bill: It Will be Vetoed by the Governor of Illinois if Passed.”.

[60].   “Barry’s Anti-Trust View,” The New York Times, March 19, 1897.

[61].   “The Municipal Assembly: Important Resolutions Offered at Yesterday’s Meeting of City Council,” The New York Times, February 16, 1898.

[62].   “Police Power. Department Stores,” The Virginia Law Register 6, no. 5 (1900): 363.

[63].   “War on Department Stores,” The New York Times, January 15, 189.

[64].   J. A. Hill, “Taxes on Department Stores,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 15, no. 2 (1901), 299, https://www.jstor.org/stable/1884900#metadata_info_tab_contents.

[65].   Ibid.

[66].   “Police Power. Department Stores,” 36.

[67].   “Constitutional Law. Department Stores. Police Power. Taxation. Statutes. Validity. State ex rel. Wyatt v. Ashbrook et al., 55 S. W. 627 (Mo.),” The Yale Law Journal 9, no. 7 (1900): 330, https://www.jstor.org/stable/782012#metadata_info_tab_contents.

[68].   Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John Park & Sons. Co, 220 U.S. 373 (1911).

[69].   Ibid.

[70].   Mark D. Bauer, “Department Stores on Sale: An Antitrust Quandary,” 269.

[71].   Dr. Miles Medical Co. v, John Park & Sons. Co, 220 U.S. 373 (1911).

[72].   Schwegmann Bros. v. Calvert Distillers Corp., 341 U.S. 384 (1951).

[73].   Leegin Creative Leather Prod., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877 (2007).

[74].   Lucas A. Powe Jr., The Warren Court and American Politics (Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 2001), 123.

[75].   Brown Shoe v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 181, 461, (1962).

[76].   Ibid.

[77].   Lucas A. Powe Jr., The Warren Court and American Politics (Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 2001), 181.

[78].   United States v. Von’s Grocery, 384 U.S. 270, 369, 371 (1966).

[79].   Lucas A. Powe Jr., The Warren Court and American Politics, 461.

[80].   United States v. Von’s Grocery.

[81].   Ibid.

[82].   Ibid.

[83].   Robert D. Atkinson and Michael Lind, Big Is Beautiful: Debunking the Myth of Small Business, 248.

[84].   Ibid.

[85].   Florin Maican and Matilda Orth, “Determinants of Economies of Scope in Retail,” Research institute of Industrial Economics IFN Working Paper No. 1247 (2018): 2, https://www.ifn.se/media/k0shigdn/wp1247.pdf.

[86].   Ibid.

[87].   Marc Levinson, The Great A&P, and the Struggle for Small Business in America (New York: Hill and Wang, 2011), 5–6.

[88].   Godfrey Montague Lebhar, Chain Stores in America, 1859-1950 (New York: Chain Store Publishing Corporation, 1952), 22–23.

[89].   Ibid., 29.

[90].   Ibid., 36.

[91].   Charles F. Phillips, “A History of the Kroger Grocery & Baking Company,” National Marketing Review 1, no. 3 (1936): 205, https://www.jstor.org/stable/pdf/4291319.pdf.

[92].   Ibid., 22, 45.

[93].   Walter Sumner Hayward, Chain Stores: Their Management and Operations (New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company, Inc, 1922), 7; Charles F. Phillips, “An Evaluation of Large-Scale Retailing with Emphasis on the Chain Store,” Law and Contemporary Problems 8, no. 2 (1941): 349, https://www.jstor.org/stable/1189676#metadata_info_tab_contents.

[94].   Walter Sumner Hayward, Chain Stores: Their Management and Operations, 7.

[95].   Charles F. Phillips, “An Evaluation of Large-Scale Retailing with Emphasis on the Chain Store,” 349.

[96].   Godfrey Montague Lebhar, Chain Stores in America, , 5.

[97].   Walter Sumner Hayward, Chain Stores: Their Management and Operations, 298.

[98].   Richard Schragger, “The Anti-Chain Store Movement, Localist Ideology, and the Remnants of the Progressive Constitution, 1920-1940,” Iowa Law Review 90 (2005): 1013.

[99].   Paul B. Ellickson, “The Evolution of the Supermarket Industry: From A&P to Walmart,” in Handbook on the Economics of Retailing and Distribution (London: Edward Elgar Publishing, 2016), 368–391.

[100]. Ibid.

[101]. Richard Schragger, “The Anti-Chain Store Movement,”1011.

[102]. Ibid., 1013.

[103]. Ibid., 1028.

[104]. Stanley C. Hollander, “The Effects of Industrialization,” in Small Business in American Life, edited by Stuart W. Bruchey (New York: Beard Book, 1980), 212–236.

[105]. Samuel Becker, “The Chain Store License Tax and the Fourteenth Amendment,” North Carolina Law Review 7, no. 2 (1929): 120, https://scholarship.law.unc.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1187&context=nclr.

[106]. “Statutory Restraints on Chain Store Systems,” Harvard Law Review 44, no. 3 (1931): 457–458, https://www.jstor.org/stable/1331179.

[107]. Ibid., 457.

[108]. Richard C. Schragger, “The Anti-Chain Store Movement,” 103.

[109]. State Board of Tax Commissioners v. Jackson, 283 U.S. 527 (1931), https://supreme.justia.com/cases/federal/us/283/527/.

[110]. Richard C. Schragger, “The Anti-Chain Store Movement,” 119.

[111]. Great Atlantic & Pacific Tea Co. v. Grosjean, 301 U.S. 412 (1937).

[112]. United States v. New York Great Atlantic & Pacific Tea Co., 67 F. Supp. 626 (E.D. Ill. 1946), aff’d, 173 F.2d 79 (7th Cir. 1949); Joel B. Dirlam and Alfred D. Khan, “Antitrust Law and the Big Buyer: Another Look at the A&P Case,” Journal of Political Economy 60, (1952): 118 (who discussed J.M. Clark’s criticism of the notion of perfect competition and how the A&P case “involved the kind of paradox envisaged by Clark” which is to enforce the perfect competition model and this harms the economy rather than accepting the necessary imperfect nature of competition.).

[113]. United States v. New York Great Atlantic & Pacific Tea Co.,173 F. 2d 79, 82, 88 (1949).

[114]. “A Symposium on the Fair Trade Laws: Part I: Constitutionality,” Fordham Law Review 27, no. 1 (1958): 69, https://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1586&context=flr.

[115]. L. Louise Luchsinger and Patrick M. Dunne, “Fair Trade laws. How Fair?” Journal of Marketing 42, no. 1 (1978), 50–53, https://www.jstor.org/stable/pdf/1250328.pdf; https://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1586&context=flr.

[116]. Samuel Becker, “The Chain Store License Tax and the Fourteenth Amendment,” North Carolina Law Review 7, no. 2 (1929): 120, https://scholarship.law.unc.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1187&context=nclr.

[117]. Great Atlantic & Pacific Tea Co. v. Grosjean, 301 U.S. 412 (1937).

[118]. “A Symposium on the Fair Trade Laws: Part I: Constitutionality.”

[119]. Eileen Shanahan, “’Fair Trade’ Laws Coming To An End,” The New York Times, December 13, 1975, https://www.nytimes.com/1975/12/13/archives/fair-trade-laws-coming-to-an-end-president-signs-repeal-bill.html.

[120]. Richard Schragger, “The Anti-Chain Store Movement,” 1011.

[121]. “Price Discrimination: Robinson-Patman Violation,” Federal Trade Commission, accessed July 22, 2022, https://www.ftc.gov/advice-guidance/competition-guidance/guide-antitrust-laws/price-discrimination-robinson-patman-violations.

[122]. Barry C. Lynn, “Breaking the chain: The antitrust case against Wal-Mart,” Harper Magazine, 2006, https://harpers.org/archive/2006/07/breaking-the-chain/.

[123]. “A Symposium on the Fair Trade Laws: Part I: Constitutionality.”

[124]. Louis K. Liggett Co. v. Lee, 288 U.S. 517, 565 (1933) (dissenting opinion).

[125]. Ibid.

[126]. On the difference between “hard competition” (disruptive innovation outcompeting incumbents) and “soft competition” (static, price competition putting marginal competitive constraints on competitors), see Earl W. Kintner, A Robinson-Patman Primer (London: McMillan Company, 1970), 193 (who, when discussing the Robinson-Patman Act’s defense of price discrimination being justified because of the need to meet an equally low price of a competitor, wrote “This defense has the effect of sanctioning certain instances of discriminatory concessions and constitutes a congressional resolution to encourage ‘hard competition‘—lower prices—in certain competitive situations even though, by definition, adverse competitive effects continue. The [defense constitutes a] safety [valve] against excessive pressure for ‘soft competition‘ capable of being read into Section 2(a).”).

[127]. Richard Schragger, “The Anti-Chain Store Movement,” 1011.

[128]. “Price Discrimination: Robinson-Patman Violation,” Federal Trade Commission.

[129]. Aurelien Portuese, “The Road to Antitrust’s Least Glorious Hour,” Truth on the Market, July 29, 2022.

[130]. High C. Hansen, “Robin-Patman Law: A Review and Analysis,” Fordham Law Review 51, no. 6 (1983): 1113–1218.

[131]. Purolator Prods. v. FTC, 352 F. 2d 874 (7th Cir. 1965), cert. denied, 389 U.S. 1045 (1968).

[132]. Richard Schragger, “The Anti-Chain Store Movement,” 1011.

[133]. Kroger Co. v. FTC, 438 F.2d 1372 (6th Cir.), cert. denied, 404 U.S. 871 (6th Cir. 1971).

[134]. Ibid.

[135]. Ibid.

[136]. Ryan Luchs et al., “The End of the Robinson-Patman Act? Evidence from Legal Case Data,” Management Science 56, no. 2 (2010): 2123–2133 (noting that the likelihood of being found liable under the Robinson-Patman Act “has dropped drastically because of recent Supreme Court rulings from more than 1 in 3 before 1993 to less than 1 in 20 for the period 2006–2010. The analysis also points to an increased success of the no harm to competition defense.”).

[137]. Richard Schragger, “The Anti-Chain Store Movement,” 1014.

[138]. Dan Papscun, “FTC’s Khan Eyes Old Weapon to Crack Down on New Market Players,” Bloomberg Law, July 7, 2022, https://news.bloomberglaw.com/antitrust/ftc-eyes-seldom-used-pricing-law-to-crack-down-on-market-abuse; Brian Callaci and Sandeep Vaheesan, “How an Old U.S. Antitrust Law Could Foster a Fairer Retail Sector,” Harvard Business Review, February 9, 2022, https://hbr.org/2022/02/how-an-old-u-s-antitrust-law-could-foster-a-fairer-retail-sector; Doug Kantor, “Stop Price Discrimination Against Convenience Stores,” The Wall Street Journal, December 30, 2021, https://www.wsj.com/articles/antitrust-law-price-discrimination-convenience-stores-robinson-patman-competition-11640821075; U.S. Congress, Letter to Chair Lina Khan, Commissioner Rebecca Slaughter, Commissioner Noah Phillips, Commissioner Christine Wilson (Washington, DC: U.S. Congress, March 30, 2022), https://ci.criticalimpact.com/user/31823/image/Final_Letter_to_FTC_Chair_Khan_3.30.22.pdf.

[139]. On how Neo-Brandeisians proposals are tantamount to bringing the economy back to the “Stone Age,” see Herbert Hovenkamp, “Antitrust Policy and Inequality of Wealth,” CPI Antitrust Chronicle, October 2017, https://www.competitionpolicyinternational.com/wp-content/uploads/2017/10/CPI-Hovenkamp.pdf (the Neo-Brandeisian call for a policy prohibiting “lower prices [because] small competitors might be unable to survive … would rather quickly drive the economy back into the Stone Age, imposing hysterical costs on everyone.”).

[140]. Daniel Hanner et al., “Dynamics in Mature Industry: Entry, Exit and Growth of Big-Box Retailers,” Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 24, no. 1 (2015): 22–46 (“We find that despite being a mature industry, the big box grocery retailing is remarkably dynamic … While the number of big box grocery outlets operating in the U.S. has remained roughly constant, each year roughly 7% of retail outlets either open or close … Entry by large supermarket chains, however, is much rarer, and exist by larger supermarket chains is three times as likely as entry.”).

[141]. Daniel Hanner et al., “Dynamics in Mature Industry,” 26; “The SN List: Top 25 Global Grocery Retailer,” SN Supermarket News, May 31, 2004, https://www.supermarketnews.com/archive/sn-list-top-25-global-grocery-retailers; Lauren Debter, “The World’s Largest Retailers 2022: pandemic Helps Amazon cement Its Lead,” Forbes, May 12, 2022, https://www.forbes.com/sites/laurendebter/2022/05/12/worlds-largest-retailers-2022-amazon-walmart-alibaba/.

[142]. Daniel Hanner et al., “Dynamics in Mature Industry,” 26.

[143]. David Goldfield and Blaine Brownell, Urban America: From Downtown to No Town (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1979), 352-53; Yehoshua S. Cohen, “Diffusion of an Innovation in an Urban System: The Spread of Planned Regional Shopping Centers in the United States, 1949-1968” (Ph. D Dissertation, University of Chicago, 1972).

[144]. Thomas W. Hanchett, “U.S. Tax Policy and the Shopping-Center Boom in the 1950s and 1960s,” American Historical Review 101, no. 4 (1966): 1097–1098.

[145]. Thomas W. Hanchett, “U.S. Tax Policy and the Shopping-Center Boom in the 1950s and 1960s,” American Historical Review 101, no. 4 (1966): 1097–1098.

[146]. Daniel Hanner et al., “Dynamics in Mature Industry: Entry, Exit and Growth of Big-Box Retailers,” 26.

[147]. Thomas W. Hanchett, “U.S. Tax Policy and the Shopping-Center Boom in the 1950s and 1960s.”

[148]. Robert Spector, Category Killers: The Retail Revolution and Its Impact on Consumer Culture (Massachusetts: Harvard Business School Pub., 2005), xii, 26.

[149]. Sandra Stringer Vance and Roy V. Scott, Wal-Mart: A History of Sam Walton’s Retail Phenomenon (Toronto: Maxwell Macmillan Canada, 1994), 31–32.

[150]. Ibid., 44.

[151]. Ibid.

[152]. Ibid., 33.

[153]. Robert Spector, Category Killers, 25–26.

[154]. Ibid., 32.

[155]. Ibid., 41–43.

[156]. Ibid., 45.

[157]. See, for instance, Emek Basker, “Selling a cheaper mousetrap: Wal‐Mart’s effect on retail prices,” Journal of Urban Economics 58, no. 2 (2005): 203–229; Emek Basker, “The Causes and Consequences of Wal‐Mart’s Growth,” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 21, no. 3 (2007): 177–198; Emek Basker and Michael Noel, “The Evolving Food Chain: Competitive Effects of Wal‐Mart’s Entry Into the Supermarket Industry,” Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 18, no. 4 (2009): 977–1009; Jerry Hausman and Ephraim Leibtag, “Consumer benefits from increased competition in shopping outlets: Measuring the effect of Wal‐Mart,” Journal of Applied Econometrics 22, no. 7 (2007) 1157–1177; Jerry Hausman and Ephraim Leibtag, “CPI bias from supercenters: does the BLS know that Wal‐Mart exists?” in Price Index Concepts and Measurement, edited by W. Erwin Diewert, John S. Greenlees, and Charles, R. Hulten (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2009), 203–231; Stainback, Ekl, “The spread of ‘big box’ retail firms and spatial stratification,” Sociology Compass 11, no. 4 (2017): 1–11.

[158]. Ibid.

[159]. Thomas W. Hanchett, “U.S. Tax Policy and the Shopping-Center Boom in the 1950s and 1960s,” 1097–1098.

[160]. Robert Spector, Category Killers, 21.

[161]. Ibid., 57; Dazeinfo Graphfarm, “Walmart Net Sales by Year: From FY 1970 to 2020” (Walmart Net Sales Worldwide by Year, accessed July 10, 2022), https://dazeinfo.com/2020/03/04/walmart-net-sales-worldwide-by-year-graphfarm/.

[162]. Robert Spector, Category Killers, xiii, 37, 58.

[163]. Ibid., xiii.

[164]. United States Securities and Exchange Commission, Walmart 10-K Annual Report 2022 (2020–2022 net sales for Walmart U.S. and Sam’s Club; accessed September 9, 2022), https://www.sec.gov/ix?doc=/Archives/edgar/data/0000104169/000010416922000012/wmt-20220131.htm; United States Securities and Exchange Commission, Walmart 10-K Annual Report 2019 (2017–2019 net sales for Walmart U.S. and Sam’s Club; accessed September 9, 2022), https://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/0000104169/000010416919000016/wmtform10-kx1312019.htm; United States Securities and Exchange Commission, Walmart 10-K Annual Report 2016 (2014–2016 net sales for Walmart U.S. and Sam’s Club; accessed September 9, 2022), https://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/0000104169/000010416916000079/wmtform10-kx1312016.htm; United States Securities and Exchange Commission, Walmart 10-K Annual Report 2013 (2011–2013 net sales for Walmart U.S. and Sam’s Club; accessed September 9, 2022), https://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/0000104169/000010416913000011/wmt10-k.htm; United States Securities and Exchange Commission, Walmart 10-K Annual Report 2010 (2008–2010 net sales for Walmart U.S. and Sam’s Club; accessed September 9, 2022), https://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/0000104169/000119312510071652/d10k.htm; United States Securities and Exchange Commission, Walmart 10-K Annual Report 2007(2005–2007 net sales for Walmart U.S. and Sam’s Club; accessed September 9, 2022), https://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/0000104169/000119312507065603/d10k.htm; United States Securities and Exchange Commission, Walmart 10-K Annual Report 2004 (2002v–2004 net sales for Walmart U.S. and Sam’s Club; accessed September 9, 2022), https://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/0000104169/000119312504059900/d10k.htm; United States Securities and Exchange Commission, Walmart 10-K Annual Report 2001 (1999–2001 net sales for Walmart U.S. and Sam’s Club; accessed September 9, 2022), https://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/0000104169/000102140801500157/d10ka.htm; United States Securities and Exchange Commission, Walmart 10-K Annual Report 1998 (1996–1998 net sales for Walmart U.S. and Sam’s Club; accessed September 9, 2022), https://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/104169/0000104169-98-000003.txt; United States Securities and Exchange Commission, Walmart 10-K Annual Report 1995 (1991–1995 net sales for Walmart Stores; accessed September 9, 2022), https://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/104169/0000104169-95-000004.txt; Walmart, “1990 Annual Report” (company annual report, Walmart, 1990); Walmart, “1985 Annual Report” (company annual report, Walmart, 1985); Walmart, “1990 Annual Report” (company annual report, Walmart, 1990). Walmart, “1980 Annual Report” (company annual report, Walmart, 1980); Walmart, “1975 Annual Report” (company annual report, Walmart, 1975); Walmart, “1972 Annual Report” (company annual report, Walmart, 1972).

[165]. Nguyen Thi Thu Ha, “Wal-Mart's Successfully Integrated Supply Chain and the Necessity of Establishing the Triple-A supply Chain in the 21st century,” Journal of Economics and Management 29, no. 29 (2017): 105, https://www.researchgate.net/publication/320239187_Wal-Mart's_Successfully_Integrated_Supply_Chain_and_the_Necessity_of_Establishing_the_Triple-A_supply_Chain_in_the_21st_century.

[166]. Sandra Stringer Vance and Roy V. Scott, Wal-Mart: A History of Sam Walton’s Retail Phenomenon (Toronto: Maxwell Macmillan Canada, 1994), 11, 31.

[167]. Ibid., 11.

[168]. William J. Regan, “Self-Service in Retailing,” Journal of Marketing 24, no. 4 (1960): 46, https://www.jstor.org/stable/pdf/1248404.pdf.  

[169]. “The Big Box Decade,” Chain Store Age 75, no. 13 (1999): 98, https://search-ebscohost-com.ezproxylocal.library.nova.edu/login.aspx?direct=true&db=buh&AN=2647530&site=ehost-live.

[170]. Ibid.

[171]. Virginia Postrel, “Economic Scene; Lessons in keeping business humming, courtesy of Wal-mart U.,” The New York Times, February 28, 2022, https://www.nytimes.com/2002/02/28/business/economic-scene-lessons-in-keeping-business-humming-courtesy-of-wal-mart-u.html.

[172]. Ibid.

[173]. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Annual Labor Productivity and Costs (productivity data for General merchandise stores, including warehouse clubs and supercenters, NAICS: 45231, accessed August 25, 2022), https://www.bls.gov/productivity/news-releases.htm.

[174]. Stacy Mitchell, Bix-Box Swindle. The True Cost of Mega-Retailers and the Fight for America’s Independent Businesses (Massachusetts: Beacon Press, 2007), 19.

[175]. Daniel Hanner et al., “Dynamics in Mature Industry,” 31.

[176]. Anthony Bianco et al., “Is Wal-Mart Too Powerful? Low prices are great, But Wal-Mart’s dominance create problems—for suppliers, workers, communities, and even American culture,” Business Week, October 6, 2003, https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2003-10-05/is-wal-mart-too-powerful.  

[177]. Barry C. Lynn, “The Case for Breaking Up Walmart,” Foreign Policy, April 29, 2013, https://foreignpolicy.com/2013/04/29/the-case-for-breaking-up-walmart/; Barry Lynn, “Breaking the Chain,” Harper’s Magazine, July 2006, https://harpers.org/archive/2006/07/breaking-the-chain/.

[178]. Barry C. Lynn, “The Case for Breaking Up Walmart”; Barry Lynn, “Breaking the Chain.”

[179]. Stacy Mitchell, “Wal-Mart Charged With Predatory Pricing,” Institute for Local Self-Reliance, November 1, 2000, https://ilsr.org/walmart-charged-predatory-pricing/.

[180]. Ibid.

[181]. John Schmeltzer, “Wal-Mart’s Price Tactics Upheld,” Chicago Tribune, January 10, 1995, https://www.chicagotribune.com/news/ct-xpm-1995-01-10-9501100271-story.html.

[182]. Anthony J. Dukes, “Wal-Mart and price discrimination,” Phi Kappa Phi Forum 83, no. 3 (2003), https://go.gale.com/ps/i.do?id=GALE%7CA108266604&sid=googleScholar&v=2.1&it=r&linkaccess=abs&issn=15385914&p=AONE&sw=w&userGroupName=anon%7E707d78a2.   

[183]. Wal-Mart Stores, Inc. v. American Drugs, Inc, 319 Ark. 214, 891 S.W.2d 30 (1995), https://law.justia.com/cases/arkansas/supreme-court/1995/94-235-0.html.

[184]. Nolan E. Clark et al., Brief of the Federal Trade Commission As Amicus Curiae in Support of Wal-Mart Stores, Inc.’s Motion to Dismiss (Washington D.C.: Federal Trade Commission), https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/amicus_briefs/snider-et-al-v-wal-mart-stores-inc/p854622_walmart.pdf.

[185]. Emily Badger, “Why Anti-big Box Laws May Actually Be Bad for Small Retailers,” Bloomberg, January 31, 2014, https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2014-01-31/why-anti-big-box-laws-may-actually-be-bad-for-small-retailers.

[186]. Tingyu Zhou, “Does Entry Regulation of Big-box Stores Protect the Retail Sector? Evidence from Store Cap Ordinances in the U.S.” (paper, Concordia University John Molson School of Business, January 2017), 1, https://www.aeaweb.org/conference/2017/preliminary/paper/N9QTHth9.

[187]. Jennifer Evans-Cowley, “Practice Big Box Regulation” (industry report, American Planning Association, December 2005), https://planning-org-uploaded-media.s3.amazonaws.com/document/Zoning-Practice-2005-12.pdf; “Rockville closer to regulation on big-box stores,” Washington Business Journal, April 10, 2000, https://www.bizjournals.com/washington/stories/2000/04/10/daily1.html.

[188].Timothy J. Muris and Jonathan E. Nuechterlein, “Antitrust in the Internet Era: The Legacy of United States v. A&P,” Review of Industrial Organization 54, no. 4 (2019): 651-681.

[189]. “History of E-Commerce: Facts, Stats & Tips on What’s Next,” The George Washington University School of Business, https://healthcaremba.gwu.edu/history-of-ecommerce/; “1982: Boston Computer Exchange – Pivotal Moments,” Pivotal, January 2021, https://pivotal.digital/blog/1982-boston-computer-exchange-pivotal-moments.

[190]. Carmen Ang, “Timeline: Key Events in the History of Online Shopping,” Visual Capitalist, July 5, 2021, https://www.visualcapitalist.com/sp/history-of-online-shopping/; “The Internet – Nifty 50,” National Science Foundation, April 2000, https://www.nsf.gov/about/history/nifty50/theinternet.jsp.

[191]. Barbara E. Khan, The Shopping Revolution. How Successful Retailers Win Customers in an Era of Endless Disruption (Pennsylvania: Wharton School Press, 2018), 27.

[192]. Ibid.

[193]. Ibid, 8.

[194]. Ibid.

[195]. Bryan Lufkin, “The Curious Origins of Online Shopping,“ BBC, July 26, 2020, https://www.bbc.com/worklife/article/20200722-the-curious-origins-of-online-shopping; “Our History,” eBay, accessed July 17, 2022, https://www.ebayinc.com/company/our-history/.

[196]. “About,” Overstock, accessed July 17, 2022, https://www.overstock.com/about.

[197]. Umme Hani, “The A-Z of Google Shopping History,” CED Commerce, September 27, 2021, https://cedcommerce.com/blog/google-shopping-history/; Jason Del Rey, “Meet Wish, the $3 Billion App That Could Be the Next Walmart,”Vox, December 28, 2015, https://www.vox.com/2015/12/28/11621724/meet-wish-the-3-billion-app-that-could-be-the-next-walmart; Deborah Liu, “Marketplace Turns Two: introducing New AI Features and More,” Meta, October 2, 2018, https://about.fb.com/news/2018/10/marketplace-turns-two/.

[198]. Dilip Vamanan, “How to Sell on Walmart for Beginners – Complete Marketplace Guide,” Sellerapp, January 27, 2022, https://www.sellerapp.com/blog/walmart-marketplace/; George Hatch, “Target and Target+ Growth in 2020,” Pattern, March 4, 2021, https://pattern.com/blog/target-and-target-plus-growth/.

[199]. Jessica Young, “What are the top online marketplaces?” Digital Commerce 360, February 25, 2022, https://www.digitalcommerce360.com/article/infographic-top-online-marketplaces/.

[200]. Clayton M. Christensen and Richard S. Tedlow, “Patterns of Disruption in Retailing,” Harvard Business Review 78, no. 1 (2000): 42–45 (noting, “Historically experts have underestimated the ultimate reach of disruptive technologies.”).

[201]. Antitrust in the Internet Era: The Legacy of United States v. A&P 45 (“Blinded by their perception of the initial limitations of the new technology, they failed to appreciate the strength of the innovators’ motivation to move from the fringes of commerce to its mainstream.”).

[202]. Barbara E. Khan, The Shopping Revolution. How Successful Retailers Win Customers in an Era of Endless Disruption (Pennsylvania: Wharton School Press, 2018), 8.

[203]. Robert Lenzner, “Amazon Celebrates 20 Years of Stupendous Growth As ‘Earth’s Most Customer-Centric Company,” Forbes, April 24, 2018, https://www.forbes.com/sites/robertlenzner/2018/04/24/amazon-celebrates-20-years-of-stupendous-growth-as-earths-most-customer-centric-company/.

[204]. See, for instance, Jeff Bezos in a conversation with Harvard Business Review’s senior editors who said: “When I’m talking with people outside the company, there’s a question that comes up very commonly: ‘What’s going to change in the next five to ten years?’ But I very rarely get asked ‘What’s not going to change in the next five to ten years?’ [Customers] want selection, low prices, and fast delivery … So we know that when we put energy into defect reduction, which reduces our cost structure and thereby allows lower prices, that will be paying us dividends then years from now. If we keep putting energy into that flywheel, ten years from now it’ll be spinning faster and faster.” Cited in Barbara E. Khan, The Shopping Revolution. How Successful Retailers Win Customers in an Era of Endless Disruption, (Pennsylvania: Wharton School Press, 2018), 28.

[205]. Michael Mandel, “Amazon, Whole Foods, and the Simple Arithmetic of Household Time,” Progressive Policy Institute, June 30, 2017, https://www.progressivepolicy.org/blogs/amazon-whole-foods-simple-arithmetic-household-time/.

[206]. Emily Dayton, “Amazon Statistics You Should Know: opportunities to make the most of America’s Top Online Marketplace,” Big Commerce, https://www.bigcommerce.com/blog/amazon-statistics/#amazon-everything-to-everybody; “Our Retail Divisions,” Walmart, accessed Jul 19, 2022, https://corporate.walmart.com/newsroom/2005/01/06/our-retail-divisions.

[207]. Pradeep K Chintagunta et al., “Quantifying Transaction Costs in Online/Off-line Grocery Channel Choice,” Marketing Science 31, no. 1 (2011): 99, https://pubsonline.informs.org/doi/pdf/10.1287/mksc.1110.0678.

[208]. Nick Heethuis, “Amazon 1P vs. 3P: What’s The Difference?” Forbes, October 19, 2021, https://www.forbes.com/sites/theyec/2021/10/19/amazon-1p-vs-3p-whats-the-difference/; Carina McLeod, “Amazon Vendor Contract Negotiations: What You Need to Know,” eComEngine, https://www.ecomengine.com/blog/vendor-contract-negotiations.

[209]. Nick Heethuis, “Amazon 1P vs. 3P: What’s The Difference?” Forbes, October 19, 2021, https://www.forbes.com/sites/theyec/2021/10/19/amazon-1p-vs-3p-whats-the-difference/.

[210]. Statista, US Amazon First-Party and Third-Party E-Commerce Sales Share 2012-2020 (Amazon sales, accessed July 18, 2022), https://www.statista.com/statistics/917414/amazon-first-party-third-party-ecommerce-total-online-retail-sales-share/.

[211]. Jean-Francois Houde et al., “Economies of Density in E-Commerce: A Study of Amazon’s Fulfillment Center Network” (working paper, National Bureau of Economic Research, Massachusetts, 2017), 1, https://www.nber.org/system/files/working_papers/w23361/revisions/w23361.rev1.pdf; Cora Lewis, “How Amazon Halved Its Shipping Costs in a Decade,” BuzzFeed News, May 1, 2017, https://www.buzzfeednews.com/article/coralewis/how-amazon-halved-its-shipping-costs-in-a-decade.

[212]. Jean-Francois Houde et al., “Economies of Density in E-Commerce: A Study of Amazon’s Fulfillment Center Network” (working paper, National Bureau of Economic Research, Massachusetts, 2017), 43, https://www.nber.org/system/files/working_papers/w23361/revisions/w23361.rev1.pdf.

[213]. Cora Lewis, “How Amazon Halved Its Shipping Costs in a Decade,” BuzzFeed News, May 1, 2017, https://www.buzzfeednews.com/article/coralewis/how-amazon-halved-its-shipping-costs-in-a-decade.

[214]. “Who We Are,” Amazon, accessed July 17, 2022, https://www.aboutamazon.com/about-us/leadership-principles.

[215]. Statista, Amazon: Global Net Retail Sales 2017-2027 (net retail sales value of Amazon worldwide from 2017 to 2027; accessed July 17, 2022), https://www.statista.com/statistics/1264135/amazon-net-sales/; Statista, Target: Net Sales in the United States 2015-2021 (Net sales of Target in the United States from 2015 to 2021; accessed July 17, 2022), https://www.statista.com/statistics/1113236/net-sales-of-target-in-the-us/.

[216]. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Annual Labor Productivity and Costs (productivity data for General merchandise stores, including warehouse clubs and supercenters, NAICS: 45231; and Electronic shopping and mail-order houses, NAICS 45411, accessed August 25, 2022), https://www.bls.gov/productivity/news-releases.htm.

[217]. Jake Ward, “The Value in Online Marketplaces,” Protocol, https://www.protocol.com/Sponsored-Content/online-marketplaces-value-to-small-businesses.

[218]. Ibid.

[219]. Lina M. Khan, “Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox,” Yale Law Journal 126, no. 3 (2017): 710–805.

[220]. See, for instance, Jerrold Nadler and David N. Cicilline, Investigation of Competition in Digital Markets (Washington, DC: U.S. House Committee on the Judiciary, 2020), https://judiciary.house.gov/uploadedfiles/competition_in_digital_markets.pdf (assuming that Amazon “has monopoly power over many small and medium-sized businesses that do not have a viable alternative to Amazon for reaching online consumers.”); See also Aurelien Portuese, “’Please, Help Yourself’: Toward a Taxonomy of Self-Preferencing” (ITIF, October 2021), https://www2.itif.org/2021-self-preferencing-taxonomy.pdf; Aurelien Portuese, “Is Congress Committed to Making American Consumers’ Lives Costlier?” WLF Legal Pulse, January 12, 2022, https://www.wlf.org/wp-content/uploads/2022/01/011122Portuese_LP.pdf.

[221]. American Innovation and Choice Online Act, S. 2992, 117th Cong. (2021–2022), https://www.congress.gov/bill/117th-congress/senate-bill/2992/text; Platform Competition and Opportunity Act of 2021, S. 3197, 117th Cong. (2021-2022), https://www.congress.gov/bill/117th-congress/senate-bill/3197/text; Ending Platform Monopolies Act, H.R. 3825, 117th Cong. 2021-2022), https://www.congress.gov/bill/117th-congress/house-bill/3825/text.

[222]. Aurelien Portuese, “Is Congress Committed to Making American Consumers’ Lives Costlier?” Washington Legal Foundation, January 12, 2022, https://www.wlf.org/wp-content/uploads/2022/01/011122Portuese_LP.pdf.

[223]. Pramila Jayapal, “Jayapal and Lawmakers Release Anti-Monopoly Agenda for ‘A Stronger Online Economy: Opportunity, Innovation, Choice,’”” news release, June 11, 2021, https://jayapal.house.gov/2021/06/11/antitrust-legislation/.

[224]. Jay Caruso, “The Ending Platform Monopolies Act targets Big Tech,” Washington Examiner, June 17, 2021, https://www.washingtonexaminer.com/business/the-ending-platform-monopolies-act-targets-big-tech.

[225]. Alex Reinauer, “Ten Terrible Tech Bills from the 117th Congress: Ending Platform Monopolies Act,” Competitive Enterprise Institute, May 13, 2022, https://cei.org/blog/ten-terrible-tech-bills-from-the-117th-congress-ending-platform-monopolies-act/.

[226]. Ending Platform Monopolies Act, H.R. 3826, 117th Cong. 2021–2022), https://www.congress.gov/bill/117th-congress/house-bill/3826/text; Julie Carlson, “The Platform Competition and Opportunity Act Is a Solution in Search of a Problem” (ITIF, January 31, 2022), https://itif.org/publications/2022/01/publications/2022/01/31/platform-competition-and-opportunity-act-solution-search-problem/.

[227]. Paulo Rotella Junior et al., “Mergers and Acquisitions: An Efficiency Evaluation,” Applied Mathematics 4, no. 11 (2013): 1584, https://www.researchgate.net/publication/262560310_Mergers_and_Acquisitions_An_Efficiency_Evaluation.

[228]. Julie Carlson, “The Platform Competition and Opportunity Act Is a Solution in Search of a Problem” (ITIF, January 31, 2022), https://itif.org/publications/2022/01/publications/2022/01/31/platform-competition-and-opportunity-act-solution-search-problem/.

[229]. Aurelien Portuese, “The Digital Markets Act: European Precautionary Antitrust” (ITIF Report, May 2021), https://www2.itif.org/2021-digital-markets-a4.pdf; Aurelien Portuese, “The Digital Markets Act: A Triumph of Regulation Over Innovation” (ITIF Report, August 2022), https://www2.itif.org/2022-digital-markets-act.pdf; Aurelien Portuese, “The Digital Markets Act” The Path to Overregulation,” CPI Columns, June 2022, https://www.competitionpolicyinternational.com/wp-content/uploads/2022/06/EU-Column-June-2022-2-Full.pdf.

[230]. European Commission, “Antitrust: Commission opens investigation into possible anti-competitive conduct of Amazon,” press release, July 17, 2019, https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/ip_19_4291; European Commission, Opening of Proceedings Against Amazon (opening proceedings, European Commission, July 17, 2019), https://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/cases/dec_docs/40462/40462_6210_9.pdf; European Commission, “Antitrust: Commission Sends Statement of Objections to Amazon for the Use of Non-Public Independent Seller Data and Opens Second Investigation Into Its E-Commerce Business Practices,” press release, November 10, 2020, https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/ip_20_2077; European Commission, “Antitrust: Commission seeks feedback on commitments offered by Amazon concerning marketplace seller data and access to Buy Box and Prime,” press release, July 14, 2022, https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/ip_22_4522; Washington State Office of the Attorney General, “AG Ferguson investigation shuts down Amazon price-fixing program nationwide,” news release, January 26, 2022, https://www.atg.wa.gov/news/news-releases/ag-ferguson-investigation-shuts-down-amazon-price-fixing-program-nationdewi; Bryan Koenig, “DC AG Appealing Toss of Amazon Antitrust Suit,” Law360.com, August 25, 2022, https://www.law360.com/articles/1524464/dc-ag-appealing-toss-of-amazon-antitrust-suit; U.K. Competition and Markets Authority, “CMA investigates Amazon over suspected anti-competitive practices,” press release, July 6, 2022, https://www.gov.uk/government/news/cma-investigates-amazon-over-suspected-anti-competitive-practices; Bundeskartellamt, “Bundeskartellamt obtains far-reaching improvements in the terms of business for sellers on Amazon’s online marketplaces,” news release, July 17, 2019, https://www.bundeskartellamt.de/SharedDocs/Meldung/EN/Pressemitteilungen/2019/17_07_2019_Amazon.html; Bundeskartellamt, “Amazon, Inc. Paramount significance for competition across markets formally determined,” July 6, 2022, https://www.bundeskartellamt.de/SharedDocs/Entscheidung/EN/Fallberichte/Missbrauchsaufsicht/2022/B2-55-21.pdf?__blob=publicationFile&v=3; Elvira Pollina and Maria Pia Quaglia, “Italy fines Amazon record $1.3 billion for abuse of market dominance,” Reuters, December 9, 2021, https://www.reuters.com/technology/italys-antitrust-fines-amazon-113-bln-euros-alleged-abuse-market-dominance-2021-12-09/; “Amazon slapped with record 4 million euro fine by French court,” RFI, September 4, 2019, https://www.rfi.fr/en/france/20190904-us-online-seller-amazon-slapped-4-million-euro-record-fine-french-court.

[231]. White House, Executive Order on Promoting Competition in the American Economy (Washington, DC: White House, July 9, 2021), https://www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/presidential-actions/2021/07/09/executive-order-on-promoting-competition-in-the-american-economy/; Robert D. Atkinson et al., “Reflections on President Biden’s Executive Order on Competition” (ITIF, July 2021), https://www2.itif.org/2021-biden-competition-executive-order.pdf.

[232]. White House, Executive Order on Promoting Competition in the American Economy.

[233]. Ibid.

[234]. Federal Trade Commission, Statement of Regulatory Priorities (Washington, DC: Federal Trade Commission, December 10, 2021), https://www.reginfo.gov/public/jsp/eAgenda/StaticContent/202110/Statement_3084_FTC.pdf/.

Back to Top