Skip to content
ITIF Logo
ITIF Search
Don’t Block Geoblocking

Don’t Block Geoblocking

June 9, 2016

Featured Image

One reason information technologies have delivered huge benefits to the world—and promise even greater gains in the future—is that they lower the cost of producing high-value, information-driven products and services, from movies and games to software tools. Yet, because these information products are fundamentally different from physical goods or services, their pricing models have often led to confusion. An example of this is the current debate in Australia about geoblocking, the practice of varying the availability or price of a digital good or service, market by market, depending upon the location of the purchaser.

A recent draft report by the Australian Government’s Productivity Commission renewed longstanding complaints against geoblocking. Citing a previous report by the Australian House of Representatives, plus pricing data from 2012, the report found that Australians paid an average of 50 percent more for digital goods than did Americans. In response to this perceived unfairness, the commission urged copyright holders to provide more timely and less costly access to digital works. It also encouraged the government to affirm that consumers may use software that circumvents geoblocking technology without violating Australian copyright laws.

Such a policy could reduce the availability of products and services that people want or need while actually raising consumer prices. A 2014 report by the Information Technology and Innovation Foundation shows why this is so and why the existing rules may produce the greatest consumer choice at the lowest prices over the long term.

The price of information-driven goods can differ internationally for many reasons. For instance, the House of Representatives report noted that Australian prices usually include sales tax while U.S. prices do not. Fluctuations in exchange rates can also result in a divergence between posted prices. Finally, many electronic products require advertising and consumer service, which has to be spread out over a smaller market, thereby losing some economies of scale.

Information-driven goods are different from physical goods in other respects, too. Normally, competition drives the price of a good down near its marginal cost. At this price, the cost of producing one more unit is equal to its value to the person who buys it. But because music, movies, and software programs normally entail high up-front costs but very low marginal cost, producers have to charge a higher price in order to recoup costs and make a profit.

Copyright law allows this to happen by giving producers the right to prevent people from using copyrighted materials without the permission of the rights holder. But if a copyright holder has to charge everyone everywhere the same price, it will restrict production and raise prices, because the marginal value of new sales at a universal price for the widest-possible market would be more than offset by the lost opportunity to set higher prices for customers who are willing to pay more.

By contrast, rules that allow copyright holders to charge different prices to different consumers benefit society by encouraging greater distribution at a lower average price overall. A movie studio might charge a higher price in a developed country while charging a lower price in developing countries. Because rich markets are normally less sensitive to price, this practice normally favors poorer consumers. But it can only exist if price discrimination and geoblocking is protected. If consumers are allowed to arbitrage the market, the producer will create less and charge higher prices.

Copyright holders remain constrained by market forces, however. First, they cannot compel any consumer to pay more than the product is worth to him or her. As a result, we can be sure that Australian consumers benefit from every purchase they make. Second, beyond a certain point, raising prices lowers total revenue. Third, it is hard to think of a more competitive or dynamic industry than that for many information goods. Consumers have literally hundreds of thousands of movies, songs, games, and software applications to choose from. Just consider how much is now available to stream legally for free.

There is another reason to be wary of attempts to interfere with copyright owners’ ability to set prices and availability. As the Australian Treasury and the Attorney General’s Department pointed out to the House of Representatives, attempts to ban geoblocking can force offshore sellers to withdraw from the Australian market or eliminate local distributors. The Australian Internet market is rapidly developing and policymakers should let this process play out before interfering.

Public policy requires balancing social risks. The tremendous potential of information technology is likely to revolutionize markets, reduce prices, and increase quality, productivity, and living standards. Instead of concentrating on the risk that Australian consumers might temporarily be paying higher prices than those in the world’s most dynamic market, the government should worry about maximizing the supply of new information products of all types.

Back to Top