Innovation Economics: The Race for Global Advantage
About the Book
Innovation Economics: The Race for Global Advantage delivers a critical wake-up call: a fierce global race for innovation advantage is under way, and while other nations are making support for technology and innovation a central tenet of their economic strategies and policies, America lacks a robust innovation policy. Unless the United States enacts public policies to reflect this reality, Americans face the relatively lower standards of living associated with a noncompetitive national economy. The authors explore how a weak innovation economy not only contributed to the Great Recession but is delaying America's recovery from it and how innovation in the United States compares with that in other developed and developing nations.
The book is a detailed, pragmatic road map for America to regain its global innovation advantage by 2020, as well as maximize the global supply of innovation and promote sustainable globalization.
- Robert D. Atkinson and Stephen Ezell, Innovation Economics: The Race for Global Advantage (Yale University Press: September 4, 2012), ISBN: 978-0-300-16899-0.
Praise
“Innovation Economics: The Race for Global Advantage offers a frank assessment of many of the underlying causes of our economic challenges and helps explain why recovery has remained so elusive. Rob Atkinson and Stephen Ezell have collaborated on a timely call to action: America can compete and win the global economic race, but only if we change our mindset and update many of our policies.” — Sen. Mark Warner (D-VA)
“The United States is increasingly being left behind in the global competition for high-value production and jobs. While this trend is lowering our standard of living, there are steps government can take to stem this decline, such as making STEM education a national priority and pursuing a 21st century growth agenda that acknowledges the important role that innovation plays. Innovation Economics is an important read for those of us concerned about our nation’s long-term economic challenges but optimistic about solutions to improve our future in our own time.” — Rep. Richard Hanna (R-NY)
“Innovation Economics offers the most pragmatic guideposts for American and global economic renewal today. I recommend it for every leader in or out of office.“ — Calestous Juma, Harvard Kennedy School
“As a long-time analyst of the trends shaping the global economy, I am struck by the increasing number of economic and political leaders that do not grasp how serious the structural economic problems facing America are. I hope they read Innovation Economics. It “speaks truth power” with candor, reason and wit and offers fresh thinking and a path forward. Rob Atkinson and Stephen Ezell have been making important contributions and better ideas about economic policy for years. Their new book is eye-opening and alarming and arrives at a critical time.” — Lenny Mendonca, McKinsey Global Institute
“Atkinson and Ezell provide the definitive guide to innovation and its impact on economic prosperity. If you care about innovation, you need to read this book.” — Justin Rattner, Chief Technology Officer, Intel
Select Press: Op-Eds, News Articles, Reviews
- David Brooks, “Carpe Diem Nation,” The New York Times, February 11, 2013.
- Robert D. Atkinson and Stephen J. Ezell, “The Government’s Role in Spurring Innovation,” Federal Computer Week, November 30, 2012.
- Steve Lohr, “The Seeds That Federal Money Can Plant,” The New York Times, October 6, 2012.
- Tyler Cowen, “Innovation Economics,” review in Marginal Revolution, September 23, 2012.
- Eamonn Fingleton, “How America's Hapless Taxpayers Are Funding China’s Growth,” Forbes, September 10, 2012.
- Robert D. Atkinson, “America’s Looming IP Drain,” Huffington Post, September 20, 2012.
- Robert D. Atkinson and Stephen Ezell, “Why U.S. Economy Imploded and Why Recovery is So Slow,” The Hill, September 9, 2012.
- Robert D. Atkinson, “Should We Expect Multinationals to Be Loyal?” The Globalist, September 19, 2012.
- Ike Brannon, “The Pitfalls of Reforming a Broken System,” Regulation, Cato Institute, Winter 2012–2013.
- The Economist, “How Not to be Left Behind: Why America Cannot See that it is Losing Traction,” book review, October 13, 2012.
About Innovation Economics: The Economic Doctrine for the 21st Century
While the U.S. economy has been transformed by the forces of technology, globalization, and entrepreneurship, the doctrines guiding economic policymakers have not kept pace and continue to be informed by 20th century conceptualizations, models and theories. Without an economic theory and doctrine that matches the new realities, it will be harder for policymakers to take the steps that will most effectively foster growth.
Fortunately within the last decade a new theory and narrative of economic growth grounded in innovation has emerged. Known by a range of terms—“institutional economics,” “new growth economics,” “evolutionary economics,” “neo-Schumpertarian economics,” or just plain “innovation economics”—this new economics reformulates the traditional economic growth model so that knowledge, technology, entrepreneurship, and innovation and are now positioned at the center, rather than seen as forces that operate independently.
But up to now, innovation economics, and innovation policy, has not fully been appreciated by policymakers, in large part because the dominant economic policy models advocated by most economic advisors and implicitly held by most policymakers largely ignore innovation and technology-led growth, in favor of macroeconomic issues, such as tax cuts on individuals, budget surpluses, or social spending, which at the end of the day pale in significance to innovation in driving economic growth.
In contrast, “innovation economics” recognizes the reality that a global, knowledge-based economy requires a new approach to national economic policy based less on capital accumulation, budget surpluses, or social spending and more on smart support for the building blocks of private sector growth and innovation.
Rather than focus on ensuring that prices accurately reflect costs to drive what conventional economists call allocative efficiency, innovation economists argue that the lion’s share of economic growth is determined by productivity and innovation.
Rather than focus principally on markets assumed to be in equilibrium and individuals assumed to be acting rationally in response to price signals along supply and demand curves, innovation economics recognizes that innovation and productivity growth take place in the context of institutions. In this sense it is based on the notion that it is only through actions taken by workers, companies, entrepreneurs, research institutions, and governments that an economy’s productive and innovative power is enhanced. As a result, when examining how the economy creates wealth, innovation economics is focused on a different set of questions:
- Are entrepreneurs taking risks to start new ventures?
- Are companies investing in technological breakthroughs and is government supporting the technology base (e.g., funding research and the training of scientists and engineers)?
- Are regional clusters of firms and supporting institutions fostering innovation?
- Are research institutions transferring knowledge to companies?
- Are our trade policies working to ensure a level playing field for American companies?
- Are workers getting skilled and are companies organizing production in ways that utilize those skills?
- Are policymakers avoiding erecting protections for companies against more innovative competitors?
- And perhaps most importantly, are policies supporting the ubiquitous adoption of advanced information technologies and the broader digital transformation of society and the economy?
This site is devoted to helping policymakers better understand the doctrine of innovation economics and its implications for a host of economic policy challenges both broadly cutting across issues (e.g., tax policy, regulatory policy, spending and investment policy, and trade policy) and specifically to particular substantive areas (e.g., energy policy, retirement security, housing, anti-trust, and competitiveness policy). We believe that such a project is critical if nations are to reshape their economic policies to effectively spur widely shared growth in the 21st century. Indeed, it is critical to the long term welfare of nations’ citizens.
Over 70 years ago, as policymakers were in the grasp of outmoded economic doctrines that hindered them from effectively responding to the Great Depression, John Maynard Keynes famously stated, “Practical men, who believe themselves to be quite exempt from any intellectual influences, are usually the slaves of some defunct economist.” These words are as true today as when Keynes wrote them, and our challenge today is to open up the dialogue over economic policy to include a new doctrine of innovation economics.